Title Author(s) Citation Issue Date Type Japan’s Interest in the Pacific Trade Expansion : PAFTA Re-Considered Kojima, Kiyoshi Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 9(1): 1-31 1968-06 Departmental Bulletin Paper Text Version publisher URL http://hdl.handle.net/10086/8051 Right Hitotsubashi University Repository JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION = PAFTA RE-CONSIDERED* By KIYOSHI KOJIMA** I . Introdaction International trade policies are volatile and searching for fresh directions in the PostKennedy Round situation. A restructuring of Atlantic trade can be anticipated. In the Pacific region, there is need to develop measures for expanding trade among advanced countries (the United States of America, Canada, Japan, Australia and New Zealand) and trade and aid with the developing countries of Asia and Latin America, in the hope of promoting closer economic co-operation and, perhaps, the establishment of a Pacific Free Trade Area.1 This paper examines, first, recent trends in the Pacific trade, based upon a trade matrix by country s well as by commodity group, and the intensity of trade among the five Pacific countries and their trade with Asian and Latin American developing countries. The analysis suggests that trade among the five Pacific countries has tended to become more inter-dependent, that there has been increased economic co-operation between those countries and, at the same time, that there are som,e weaker links which should be strengthened for further trade expans ion . Secondly, the possible static effects of eliminating tariffs among flve Pacific countries are estimated on the basis of 196 trade figures. The anticipated trade expansion would be extensive and larger than the effect of the Kennedy Round tariff reductions. This suggests that the * This paper was originally presented at "The Conference on Pacific Trade and Development" held on January 11-13, 1968 in Tokyo by the Japan Economic Research Center. The paper Is mtended to revrse and amplify the author's former paper "A Pacific Economic Community and Asian Developing Countries," Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, Vo. 7, No. 1, June 1966, pp. 17-37. ** Professor (Kyo ju) of International Economics. 1 The devaluation of the pound sterling on November 18, 1967, and the uncertainty about the dollar which followed sterling devaluation, were a severe shock for Pacifc countries. They warned of the precariousness of international economic and financial co-operation within the framework of the IMF and GATT and the need for tighter international economic integration. Ten days before sterling devaluation, an important report was published by Maxwell Stamp Associates, (The Free Trede Option, Opporiunity for Britain, The Atlantic Trade Study. London, 1967), strongly advocating ' the formation of a North Atlantic Free Trade Area among the United States, Canada, and Britain. The lessons of sterling de- valuation suggest that the establishment of NAFTA will become an urgent task. Then, what course should Japan, Australia, and New Zealaid follow in the Pacific ? The NAFTA plan treats them lightly: they may be permitted to participate as associate members. From our point of view, this hardly seems satisfactory. Why should the five Pacific countries, the United States, Canada, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand, not prepare for the formation of a Pacific Free Trade Area and welcome British participa- tion ? Might not PAFTA and NAFTA be linked together through common United States-Canadian participation ? ' ' ' ' O.一トoう、oo寸 O。oうNoり、①oり ト.ONN.αoN O.鶉O、㎝ 卜.08.㎝ oっ.OO寸、一 O.oう8.oっ O.話一.oo 寸.O。うO、N oo.卜oっ寸ぜ O.8卜.oう 一.Oトマ、寸 トめゆ。うδ O.霞O、博 鴎.80、ぐq oう.O O,〇一〇う αo.oq爲 卜.一㎝O、oo一 〇.〇一寸 oo.oqゆの.oo一 一.oう㎝oう ゆ.OOH、① O.㎝〇一 卜.①雲 鴫.鋼O.H O.卜曾.肖 N.一〇①、㎝ ㎝.N卜αD.O 卜.写O.O 卜.O寸O、卜 頃.寸NH 可.コ①、oっ O.ON。o.寸 お.oう 瞬.OS、N ㎝.ooト一、一 ①.O寸卜 一.Ooうoう αD.ooN oo,0お O.コoq αD.蕊一 一.トお.N 寸.80、一 頃.NOO 卜.一トOゼ N.oう8.oう 一.寅O、oう 唱 <のP の〇一一り自昌on︾ o頸詰山 3㊤Z ℃属醸田N 。笛 .勺 .、 自身h .喝 の眉o山図 目e湖琶費国 <のP .q o℃晋邸Q 邸躍位勘一の口ぐ 械 oっ。oq。うり、〇 一。oっ8.O oう.800.oう oo,oう一 ①.8一 卜.お 〇.臼 一尋〇一 oD.O寸 H.寸 寸.一一 寸.爲oo oD.Oooq O.諾マ 寸.〇一 O、守 N.O㎝oっ αo,〇一 一.8一 N。ゆ①寸 O,認 oう.〇一 寸.N の.oっoo寸 O,卜8、一 O.oっ一寸 N.一 ト.αoト一 ㎝.OOoq 頃.卜寸 頃.oう雲 の.①ooσっ N.ON 卜.マoっO.一 〇。め日 N.一〇N 一.O 一.8 ㊤,蕊O 〇.卜O寸 ㎝.一〇 eq.寸寸 〇。OHO 寸.卜 一.Oひう寸 ①、Oコ 一.巽一、oっ マ.りH N.8卜 O.N① oっ.一8 一.㎝一 O.O①一、cq O.oo卜①、N ㎝.寸O寸 0.一①︾ 卜。寸Oマ O,総一 〇う.緯 マ,σう㊦q 〇,NO σo.NoうH oo,O卜N 崎 ト.OO N.頃卜 卜.NOoo 一.OON 卜.ゆ一 O.oooo卜、N ①.O寸 一.酪マ 頃.O酪.H 寸.卜 マ.寸oっ oo.臼 卜.oo8、一 O.卜Oマ αo.トぢ、一 oo.親oo Qo,oう寸 O.㎝專、oD O.雪oo ㎝.卜卜oo 。う,斜一.ゆ 卜.oう①一 O。萬一 αつ.N麟 O,cq8ぜ oう.寸① 一.Ooq一 oD.ooN の.OooN O.蕊 ㎝.N8㎡ 、 層定一一の5< G邸α邸門 oo,ooO一 ①.雲 卜.oo①O O。Oり○、N 卜.O。う一、寸 マ,8N、oう ①.卜oD寸、oo 一,ON一 O.ゆ尊 卜.〇一ト、一 O.§、寸 oo.oう寸 〇〇.でOoり.O oo、一ト oo.ON寸、oう 〇.竃H 卜、○ゆト、oう ト。OooO.N eq,㊤の一。の O.一話.N N,oo卜O、寸 H。詰oo.一 恥 .目く屈憲日屈の<﹄oる○ dO螺6邸山 .N,乞[ ぺ .一国■ρ⊇<↑ 超℃目邸O H.○①一 〇〇、oう諾 ①,①oQ一 N.OO一 ゆ.卜① 〇っ.守① αD.おoう 寸.OoうN oo.oDoD一 oう O,。っ專㎡ oq.毯 O.OOoD O,O卜αo、oq oo,鵠N oo.お寸 一,O寸N O。鵠ゆ、oo O.oooう寸 ㎝,一一N、一 頃.oo㎝マ、N O。霧oD N.蕊卜.一 〇〇.一一〇.寸 ①.eqト一、一 N.寸①H、N oo.oうト①.寸 oう.NOゆ.一 〇う。㎝寸一 αo。蕊一 O。oう①oう、oうN O.8寸、卜㎝ O.一〇〇〇づ O.O卜卜、O O.08、一 鷺 .︵⋮[,>P﹄①一一︵U Q国国 .出。P 喫 ︵窪一一毛8彊目︶6暫<Σ目話﹄ 、. oう.︸O①、ト一 の一一〇費国 一短o↑ ゆO①H、唱gコ一〇〇﹄①㌧50一 〇〇〇①一 .qgコ一〇り㊤一℃℃咽g 錦①一、唱g三〇〇﹄①畠αコ oo [June HITOTSUBASHl JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 2 占、目2蕊>、看薯≦↑ O.QO卜、OうトH O.H一〇.〇一 O.OoqO.寸N .℃㊤℃ロ℃國①㊤﹄“℃賃邸τ罵Σ〇三‘Q−目鳴邸q三Q鴎.のz酒の<、邸も目囲ののo山梶o山67[漕のく官o山、漕のく一﹄gの℃ロ一。のz層の< N.08.N O.Oト一、oo 卜。oD8 0う.一〇一 oっ.鳴Ooう N.專oう、oう ︻90↑ ao葺国 お石O 響983 Q国国 ℃9ヨ⇒ εo℃bo三図 邸Q帽おε< 三一爵 漕のく ご壱○ ・勒 .ぺ 9軸 .、 、①﹄Oq邸bO三の.薫3邸﹄弱の6Ph謂5臥餌6Φ唱鳳息摺‘山、属層沼莞山、O㊤∈O国‘椙OZ、℃O角邸h邸矯薯・08邸Σ60昌・⇔嘱コ5自㊤餌器お属 、煽ぞ5、bo目o図bo属。=、口邸タ届↑帽ε‘Q.口oゑ①Q.鳴ぞo﹄日而Q.燭日﹄q⇒、咽①偶aρ自、口εの箱而﹄bo旧<8℃ヨoβ邸帽のくお壱O O,N濡.一 〇D.㎝卜O 揺且貫一 .省著誘嘱弩眉旨邸β蓉聾5。コ8目㊤忌お<.8陰一塗、8−器①二“言ξ、恥篭歳b巽’9書選q“8峯お O、。うト。っ、oo O。一〇〇マ、一㎝ O.OOO O.oD8.oo O§、㎝一 〇.ooでO、一寸 O。oo一㎝、ト一 O.oooう一、〇一 〇.OOO.oo O.80.O ㎝。〇一寸、oう一 O.§、等 O。卜oっト、O ゆ.一8.O O.Oooマ、㎝ 嶋.。うoうO、oっ O.蕊oo oo。8卜、一 N.一コ O.Ooりト.〇一 〇。舘oう。のoう oっ.卜O卜 O.8一 〇。αoO一、一 マ。一〇マ、一 り,マq αo.O鋼 oo.頃〇一 O.oooooo、一 O.Oトマ.oり一 〇.〇一〇〇、卜 N.卜霧 oう.トマ ト.一自 卜.O卜 ト.㎝嵩 マ雪 N.蕊 〇う。9① 寸.卜トマ、一 O.ト一で、O▽ O。忍の oo。ト一〇う N.O親.oo oう.OOoq、蕊 N,90.N oう.O①①、NN N.一8δ マ.ooNoq、oq oo.寸8 O。O㊤頃、〇一 〇,Oト一、oD .一邸﹄燭m[ ¢邸唄﹄一 、邸哨の①属o℃目一 O.○OO、Nマ一 〇.ONoう、N一 oう.800、oう 〇う.寸O卜。マ一一 O。寸Ooり.ト一 嶋,NOooぜ マ.8N oう。oうOoD、N 一.Ooう頃 〇.一〇qoり.寸一 O.80、一 ①.oっのト ト.oうooO.oう O,αD卜 ①.O①ゆ、一 N.8で、oo 〇.肩O、① N.Ooooo O.OαD寸 で.08、N ㎝.qO 卜,一濡 N.①Ooつ N.卜耳.一 ㎝,錦oう り.08.一 寸.。うOO、一 ①。O禺 マ.OoっN O.αDO。o、N O.oっO N.Oqっ︻ O.OoうoD、ON 卜.㎝。oO.oう O.Oト一 O.①卜O、〇一 嶋.一“う一.一 O.耳 O.〇一〇.トマ 一.Oトマ、一 マ.OりN、N oう.①ooO、寸 ①.O呂.H 〇。O卜O、一 oo,りoう①^ゆ一 ㎝.。うOマ、一 〇〇.ゆ8.卜 O.一3、卜。う 卜,爲oっ、一 り,8αoづ N.ooコ ①.NαD卜.寸 ハ 一.oっ①卜 O.O卜卜㎝㎝ 卜。㎝Ooっ ト.〇一〇、一 O。話寸、一 O.O。うoう、oう 頃.N8 〇.器αつ oo.㎝田 O.N。っ一、一 oっ.マNoo αD.Nコ マ,O守 N.器O、N N.N8.N 0.一誘 O.寸OO ト.潟 一,一〇〇う O.N專.㎝ O.。うOゆ、oう O.卜αo ゆ。トお.oう 軌。① ト.嶋自 マ㎡Oマ、一 H.卜詰 の︾專.N oD.一〇〇う O.oo N.一一 O.Oコ マ.卜αD一、一 マ.卜①N、一 ゆ.一〇う寸 O.〇一 〇.マ qの〇一.一 O.卜= O。㎝① oo,苺で、寸 O.一8ぜ 一。一 O.卜卜一 〇.黛O O.OOO oっ.等卜.㎝ O,OH卜、oう一 〇う.H8、一 〇う.器一.一 卜.きoう oっ.〇一〇、一 ①.①專.㎝ N,O寸マ㎝ oo.トめO 〇.O甚 ハ 〇.トゆoo、一一 マ,O卜O、一 O。お一、N ①.のO卜 マ.卜Nマ 一.800、① N.ト一ト マ,一8.一 〇.O①一、O O.O卜oD。oう O.8 寸.守一 卜,NOoD ト.αDoっ 00.ゆで O.O卜 oう.$。o.一 〇〇.OoうN O。oo話 〇う.8H.N 一,鈷① oっ。一9 一.鈷卜 αD.まN、一 O.8マ、〇一 N。卜oqO oう.oうトO O.OOマ αo.卜NoO 卜.NO卜 N.oqO卜 喫 〇〇,頃頃N、一 O.諸一、oo O.卜O㎝ O.①〇一 qD.oう蕊 O,80、oo O,800、卜 O.3卜.O ooり頃 器お認 2 JAPAN’S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 1968] 4 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF EcoNOMlcS [ June formation of a Pacific Free Trade Area, if the five countries should so, would be effective m expanding trade, especially when the likelihood that another round of global tariff reductions may not be feasible in the coming ten to twenty years is taken into account. It is also shown how the gains from the elimination of tariffs would be distributed among the five countries and in what commodity groups the expansion of trade would be significant. Thirdly, a proposal for a Pacific Free Trade Area seems quite premature for various reasons. More practical alternatives are proposed for intensifying closer trade partnership among the five Pacific countries and for increasing aid to and trade with developing countries in Asia and Latin America. II. Recent Trends in the Pacific Trade 1 . TI VO centres in world trade The Pacific is one of the two major centres of world trade and ranks alongside Western Europe. Trade among the five advanced Pacific countries, the United States, Canada, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand, increased by 97 per cent between 1958 and 1965, from $9.16 billion to $18.02 billion, and their share in world trade rose from 7.99 per cent to 10.38 per cent (Table l). The intra-areal trade of the EEC was $6.86 billion in 1958, which was smaller than PAFTA trade, and has tripled to $9-0.84 billion in 1965. The share of intra-areal trade of the EEC in world trade has increased from 5.98 per cent in 1958 to 12.00 per cent in 1965, more rapidly than in the PAFTA trade. Taking the total trade among EEC, UK and other Western Europe as "European Trade," which has increased by 2.3 times from $22.9-3 billion in 1958 to $51.16 billion in 1965, or from 19.38 per cent to 29.45 per cent in the share of world trade, it is one of the most important and rapidly growing centres in world trade (see Table 2). With this, we can compare the "extended Pacific trade," which is the sum of the trade among countries in PAFTA, other Asia (excluding Mainland China) and Latin America. Extended Pacific area trade was $23.36 billion or 20.36 per cent of world trade in 1958, which was somewhat larger than European trade, and has increased to $37.71 billion or 21.71 per t de is another centre of world trade but it has not grown so fast as has European trade, mainly due to the stagnation in exports of primary produce from developing countries in Asia and Latin America. The extended Pacific area could be the largest centre of world trade if there were closer cent of world trade in 1965. Extended Pacific area ra , co-operation in expanding trade and development within the area, since it has greater potential in the endowment of its population, natural resou ces, and capital awaiting development than already well-developed Europe. : more rapidly t ' s has increased Furthermore, intra-areal trade amongst the five Pacific coun ne than their trade with outside countries. The ratio of intra-areal trade for the five Pacific countries taken together has increased from 32.5 per cent in 1958 to 37.3 per cent in 1965. In contrast, similar ratios for EEC were 30.1 per cent in 1958 and 43.5 per cent in 1965. The five Pacific countries taken together have increased the share of their total exports going to Asia and Latin America from 19.3 per cent in 1958 to 20.3 per cent in 1965, and that to Europe as well from 26.7 per cent to 27.9 per cent respectively (Table 2). Thus, they 5 1968] JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE ExpANSloN have spread their expansion of trade to other areas. While the share of intra-areal trade in total European trade has increased from 53.3 per cent in 1958 to 64.3 per cent in 1965, the share of European trade both with the five Pacific countries and with Asia and Latin America has decreased from 13.6 per cent to 12.4 per cent and from 11,5 per cent to 7.0 per cent respectively. This seems to reflect the inward-looking trend of European trade, which has required Australia and New Zealand to turn their eyes back towards the Pacific area. These trends may be shown more exactly by the intensity of trade indices. As shown in Table 2 (c), the intensity of intra-area trade among the five Pacific countries is fairly high, 132 in 1958 and 133 in 1965, while that of intra-European trade is much lower, 106 in 1958 TABLE 2. CONSOLIDATED TRADE MATRIX (a) Trade Matrix (milion dollars) (b) Distribution of Exports (%) (,) I t* sity of Trade B C ALA 132 127 133 116 140 147 58 46 46 1 60 1 23 144 144 88 61 51 51 63 46 40 40 upper column, 1958 middle column, 1963 lower column, 1965 PAFTA: USA, Canada, Japan, Australia and New Zealand ALA : Other Asia and Latin America Europe: United Kingdom, EEC and Other Western Europe C A B A PAFTA 99 45 Europe 50 106 95 96 6 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS [June and 96 in 1965 (although that of intra-EEC trade is very high, 184 and 224 respectively-Table 3).2 The intensity of exports from PAFTA to ALA (Asia and Latin America) is high and increasing from ll6 in 1958 to 147 in 1965, while that from Europe to ALA is low and decreasing from 63 to 45. In short, extended Pacific trade is one of the most important and rapidly growing centres in the world trade and maintains a close trade relationship between the five Pacific countries and affiliated developing countries in Asia and Latin America. 2. PAFTA trade for each member country The ratio of intra-area trade for the five Pacific countries taken together, as mentioned already, has increased from 32.5 per cent in 1958 to 37.3 per cent in 1965. The similar ratio for four countries has increased; from 25.2 per cent to 31.0 per cent for the USA, from 29.2 per cent to 36.8 per cent for Japan, from 27.5 per cent to 35.3 per cent for Australia, and from 22.8 per cent to 23,5 per cent for New Zealand; while it has decreased only for Canada from 63.0 per cent to 60.1 per cent (Table 4). The exceptional decrease in the Canadian ratio was due to her heavy increase of cereal exports to Socialist countries. The importance of exports to Europe has increased for the USA from 25 per cent in 1958 to 33 per cent in 1965 and for Japan from ll per cent to 13 per cent, while it has decreased for Australia from 50 per cent to 35 per cent, for Canada from 27 per cent to 22 per cent, and for New Zealand from 70 per cent to 65 per cent. Thus, we clearly see a growing importance of the Pacific trade for the five countries which has provided a new outlet for the three British Commonwealth countries. Taking the total exports (equals imports) of PAFTA trade as 100, the composition of intra-area trade as well as the importance of the trade with outside countries are shown in Table 5 and summarized in Fig, l. The share of Japan's exports in PAFTA trade has shown the most rapid rate of increase, rising from 9.2 per cent in 1958 to 17.3 per cent in 1965, and that of Australia has also increased from 5.0 per cent to 5.8 per cent, while the similar share has decreased for the USA from 49.2 per cent to 47.1 per cent, for Canada from 34.9 per cent to 28,5 per cent, and for New Zealand from 1,7 per cent to 1.3 per cent. The decrease in the American share was mainly due to the relative decrease of exports to Canada. The share of American exports to other three countries has increased. It is clear that Japan, Australia and the US have been the grow h centres in the expansion of PAFTA trade while Canada 2 The intensity of, say, Japan's export trade with another country is measured by the ratio of that country's share in Japanese exports to its total share in world imports. In symbols, Xjt / Mt xIOO, X/ / W-M, where Xji stands for Japanese exports to country i; Xj for total Japanese exports (= Xj*); Mt for total imports by country i; Mj for total imports by Japan; and W for total world imports. It might be argued that the denominator of Mi/(W-M/) should be W, instead of W-M,. However, this does not seem valid since Japanese imports do not constitute a demand for Japanese exports meaningfully. In the case of such an aggregated trade as the PAFTA and EEC, the formula should be Xpt /Mi xIOO' Xp / W-(Mp-Mpp) where Xp and Mp stand for the total exports and imports of the PAFTA countries and Mpp for the intra-area imports (=exports) in the PAFTA: consequently Mp-Mpp represents the imports of the PAFTA countries from the outside areas. JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 7 1968] and New Zealand have been weaker links. These trends are shown further in Fig. 1.s The share in the total PAFTA trade of Japanese imports and exports to each of the PAFTA countries has without exception increased. A similar trend can be seen in American and Australian trade with PAFTA countries other than Canada and New Zealand. TABLE 3. INTENSITY OF TR!¥DE upper column, 1958 middle column, 1963 lower column, 1965 3 Similar trends can be depicted by comparing over-time changes in the intensity of trade indices in Table 3. shown 8 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS TABLE4. [June AREAL DlsTRIBuTloN oF ExPORTs(per cent) upPer column,1958 middle column,1963 10wer column,1965 to xports rom SA 一﹃﹃ α. USA わ α 3.74 4.74 Zealand ∫.Paci且c Countries 14.87 7.24 2.36 13.87 4.35 5.80 14.40 9,0therAsia h. Latin Americ且 Kingdom ノ。 EEC 為. Other W.Europe 」. Total Imports 44.07 .54 1.06 .34 .52 .90 .55 2.14 1.07 .08 .44 .39 .56 2.18 .91 .78 1.79 12.33 .88 7.34 .40 6.63 1.63 2.20 4.11 .38 .37 .86 .13 .22 .65 4.16 1.19 .41 .00 .90 .48 3.42 .63 8.11 2.38 2.85 12.56 0.99 2.14 1.17 .50 .80 .06 1.42 1.98 6.40 4.78 0.05 .32 .48 .01 .15 .12 .10 8.82 5.77 0.60 7.08 .57 .24 .20 0.61 .25 .08 .62 .78 7.33 1.04 0.61 .83 .82 .15 .00 .95 .71 7.91 0.82 .84 .93 0.50 .74 .83 0.80 11.69 2.07 2.34 .78 .79 9 ther C. sia ゐ atin m. 0.24 25.16 .31 7.21 .46 0.98 7.73 22.75 0.87 3.49 .17 3.69 0.31 62.98 .42 9.63 .40 0.14 2.74 .67 0.74 6.73 3.66 4.31 3.39 .78 .79 .86 .08 .23 .43 .73 .82 7.57 27.50 .41 7.11 .32 5.34 0.73 29.55 18.19 .56 7.98 4.50 .98 7.62 4.44 2.46 0.17 55.63 14.15 .26 5.45 6.87 .41 8.11 5.50 1.06 22.81 8.70 3.52 0.68 32.45 .82 4.47 .85 7.26 9.01 .78 0.61 0.90 .80 .67 9.06 15.84 .47 1.63 .17 1.07 9.32 12.02 .10 3.61 .07 3.71 0.57 27.67 31.18 .58 1.39 6.53 .85 4.49 5.61 1.80 14.17 10.39 .18 .72 1.37 0.01 47.53 .12 3.97 .03 2.54 0.34 9.04 .70 .56 .06 .02 .77 9.92 4.74 6.56 .41 .01 .13 .68 .02 .93 .35 .74 .94 6.76 0.26 29.16 30.49 .80 3.92 9.67 .72 6.82 5.92 .67 .14 1.57 .E。 .87 .75 0.20 .72 .70 ther 2.80 .65 .69 2.64 4.68 13.56 .01 7.15 .81 8.15 た .66 .89 0.75 .28 .61 EC 8.62 4.55 4.67 K 3.74 15.85 .49 3.89 .92 2.85 .86 3.84 26.11 11.09 .74 .52 2.37 .57 .26 4.30 .79 .84 ノ 2 0.16 10.19 .17 0.32 .14 0.53 2.14 0.62 21.18 .58 3.39 .56 4.15 7.31 .22 .16 .52 .91 .35 .99 .85 .63 8.26 15.40 .68 1.23 .33 0.81 一一一 z. United 5.13 7.37 .29 4.71 .Z。 一一一 8.New 5.81 1.48 0.99 2.65 /Paci丘c θ us・ ralia 一一一 ‘1.Australia 7.92 9.78 7.66 0.45 ﹃一一 24.07 6。 Japan 19.14 一一一 59.45 み. Canada 4 ‘ anada apan 13.79 1.08 0.02 .70 .11 .67 .02 5.31 .85 .08 2.35 .11 .12 4.98 .74 .90 17.85 0.66 1.36 z otal x. 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 100.00 00.00 00.00 5.84 30.14 21.00 .26 2.43 1.18 .94 3.48 1.03 100.oo 5.62 16.79 32.35 16.74 .52 5.53 3.53 9.99 .10 4.93 1.64 1.62 100.00 7.12 100.00 .48 .99 9.21 20.05 10.74 .45 8.34 3.75 .29 8.21 4.35 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 3,L8α読η95840プ5初PAFZ4卿漉 In order to carry out a commodity analysis of the PAFTA trade,trade matrices of eight commodity groups are calculated from UN,Goη〃πo漉君ッTrθ463孟o孟∫5読5for1958and1965. The commodity groups are; 1〉1−goods:staple foods(rice,wheat,and other grains). 9 JAPAN’S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 19681 TABLE5. IMPoRTANcE oF EAcH CouNTRY’s ExPoRTs RELATlvE To THE ToTAL INTRA−AREAL TRADE OF FlvE PAcIFlc CouNTRIEs(per cent) upper columa,1958 middle column,1963 10wer column,1965 to xports rom α. USA ゐ. Canada Zealand ∫,Paci且C Countries 11. Latin America ralia 一37.408 9,211 2,667 1,436 2,075 0,473 32.980 − 1,188 0,596 0,174 30,479 31,086 6.882 − 5.923 一 ,039 ,628 ,288 ,530 ,877 ,700 ,696 ,213 ,737 ,191 7.560 0.833 1.233 0.921 3.967 1.191 0,683 0,081 1,056 0.325 2,240 1,374 .363 0.387 .817 0.231 1.136 0、124 .158 0,093 .691 0,077 42.73138,691 .761 0、870 .287 0.780 39.233 1.263 4,683 2.253 0.073 2.008 ,170 ,323 ,772 ,340 ,566 ,748 0,168 ,326 ,287 12,807 1。63531,880 8,598 2.39732,584 6,098 10.622 0.862 9。Other Asla .Z. 5,982 ,172 ,133 1,761 ,720 ,394 0,314 ,350 ,260 ,319 ,045 一一一 θ。 New SA Canada apan ∫Paci且c 8 us− 一一一 ‘!. Australia 4 ‘ 一一一 6, Japan α δ C. 49,168 ん 9 ther atin sia m. 34,937 9,829 8,478 x. orts .E. 1,517 2,073 8,794 ,930 ,792 ,744 ,382 2,115 4,995 1,636 0,132 ,927 ,314 ther 9,153 26,511 13,222 195,451 ,654 9,601 3,239 72,606 ,835 7,599 2,175 52,039 9,574 1,937 2,155 1,743 EC 3,288 0,812 44,465 9,157 3,647 7,269 ,635 ,840 Total 乃 ノ ,K. 8,756 4,925 15,108 6,963 7,098 z ,013 ,753 0,069 ,121 ,093 ,324 ,246 ,116 ,162 0,013 ,018 ,023 ,945 ,084 1,148 ,150 ,138 5,367 ,699 ,911 4,252 ,052 ,688 4,781 ,334 ,264 1,354 ,448 ,686 3,304 ,982 ,387 1,082 ,133 ,866 1,553 55,473 0,019 7,354 ,437 ,303 1,064 31,405 ,700 ,258 0,446 ,555 ,514 0,081 ,045 ,057 0,235 6,899 18,162 0,571 6,525 7,644 ,714 ,588 3,669 2,101 100,000 27,913 48,798 28,715 37,032 16,367 308,135 3,757 7,490 3,500 9,498 6,976 90,147 ,504 ,384 00,000 68,404 ,645 ,275 00,000 9,718 4,625 1,657 6,802 6,308 2,522 0,426 ,043 ,338 ,982 ,277 0,044 0,012 ,083 ,078 ,055 ,020 20,403 8,184 6,459 42,312 9,817 4,550 22,990 ,573 ,450 0,306 ,474 ,325 1,321 10,447 ,683 ,488 8,047 ,465 ,639 ,587 ,700 7,663 ,628 ,593 7,350 13,709 ,209 4,399 ,650 2,008 1,736 ,799 ,487 4,438 ,890 ,980 73,751 7,922 7,720 89,022 7,809 7,708 N2−9。。ds:・therf・・dstu仔s,includingPr・cessedg・・ds・4 〈π3−goods:agricultural raw materials, 瓦一goods:minerals,metals,and fuels. L、一9。。ds:1ab・ur・intensiveg・・ds・flightindustryシb・thintermediateand丘nalpr・ducts・ L2−9。。ds:1ab・ur−intensive丘na19・・ds・fheavyandchemicalindustry・rigin(cameras・sewing machines,bicycles,precision type equipment,medicine,etc.) C、一9。。ds:capital−intensiveintemediateg・・ds・fheavyandchemicalindustry・rlgin(pig。ir・n・ 4Acc。rdingt・therevisedclassi丘cati・n・fSITC,thec・verage・fc・mm・ditygr・upsisasf・Hows: 2〉1−goods:Division O4 趨一9・・ds=Secti・nsO(1essO4)and1,and94L 焼一9・・ds:Secti・ns2(less251,266,267,27,鴉)and4・ ハな一goods:Divisions27and28,and Section3(less351)。 Lユー9。。ds二Secti・ns6(1ess66,67,68,69)and8(1ess812・821・86)・and267・665・666・667・ 賜一9・・ds:541,69,733,812,821,86,951・96L C1−9。。ds:Secti・n5(less図1)and251,266,351,66(less665・666・667)・67・68・ C2−goods: Section7(1ess733〉・ 10 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS FIG. 1. [ June SHARE IN THE TOTAL INTRA-AREAL TRADE OF FIVE PACIFIC COUNTRIES: TOTAL TRADE OF EACH COUNTRY IN 1965 j'/ / USIFI Ja p. 1 4. O 47. 1 17.3 16.1 1.2 11.4 3.9 t, 42.4 l" ¥* 1' . 1 .- 0.34 l¥1jt¥t 31' l 0'7 / l.8 l t{1L / 25.91L¥¥k ¥ / 2.7 A f 1'6 l .8 C 28 . 5 -----. ¥ "t' /!o -------7.19/// _., 1;"II"I' 32'6 / 1'5 __ tt Il , / 0'7 ' -- ¥¥ ,b.. o 2 0'3 IL ¥¥llt 1 5.8 6.6 '- ¥ ¥ 0'29 ¥ , t L/ ' 1_Ol ; 'Lil 1'3 I ""2_' / l) Figures in the circle show the share of each country's exports (upper figure) to and imports (lower figure) from the Pacific countries. 2) Figures along the line show the share of each bilateral trade. 3) Solid line and circle show the increase of importance while dotted ones the decrease of importance during the period of 1958-1965. steel, chemical fibres, fertilizer, etc.). C2-goods : capital intensive heavy machines and equipment. Further, Ni- and N2-goods are aggregated as Food, N8- and N4-goods as Raw Materials Ll and L2-goods as Light Manufactures, and Cl and C2-goods as Heavy Manufactures and Chemicals, for the convenience of analysis. The composition of PAFTA trade for each country exhibits different characteristics. In Japanese trade with PAFTA countries in 1965, 94.8 per cent of exports were manufactures while 71.1 per cent of imports were primary products. Japan's trade is mainly vertical type, specializing in exports of manufactured goods. Australia and New Zealand maintain another type of vertical trade, specializing in exports of primary products: 80.0 per cent of exports were consisted of primary products in the case of Australia and 82,4 per cent in the case of New Zealand, while imports were 88.2 per cent and 84,6 per cent in manufactured goods respectively. The United States and Canada maintain a balance in the trade of manufactures as well as primary products between exports and imports: manufactured goods occupy 70.0 per cent both in exports and imports for the US and 60.5 per cent and 79.6 per cent in exports and imports respectivelv for Canada. It is to be expected, therefore, that the two countries should conduct horizontal type trade with the PAFTA countries. Relative to the growth of total PAFTA trade from 100 in 1958 to 197 in 1965, trade in heavy manufactures and chemicals (C-goods) has grown fastest (264) and followed by the trade in light manufactures (200) in which, however, the more sophisticated ones (L2-goods) have grown almost as fast as C-goods (252), while the trade in food and raw materials has grown at a slower rate than total trade (181 and 173 respectively) (see Table 6). Heavy JAPAN'S lNTEREST IN 'rnE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 1968] ll TABLE 6. TRADE IN 1965 RELATIVE TO 1958 (1958 = 100) PAFTA Trade: By Commodity Nl N2 N3 235 . 5 N4 163. 8 160 . 6 183. 5 186 . 3 Lz 252. 4 Cl 232. 4 C2 288. 9 F 180 . 7 R L C L1 173 . 4 199. 6 263 . 8 manufactures and chemicals as well as sophisticated labour intensive goods have been the leading sector in PAFTA trade, with food, raw materials and traditional light mariufactures (Ll goods) the lagging 'sector. Fig. 2 learly shows that the importance of bilateral trade in C-goods (the total share in PAFTA trade was as large as 46.5 per cent in 1965) has rapidly increased in almost all directions except.jn three unimporfant cases, i.e., Australia-the U.S., New Zealand-Australia, and New ZealandJtCanada. The U.S. and Japan are in export surplus while Canada, Australia and New Zea]and afe in import surplus. In L-goods (the total share was 20.6 per cent), except in only one case (Canada-'the U.S.), the importance of bilateral trade has also increased FIG 2. SHARE IN THE TOTAL INTRA-AREAL TRADE OF FIVE PACIFIC COUNTRIES: HEAVY MANUFACTURES AND FIG 3. SHARE IN THE TOTAL INTRA-AREAL TRADE OF FIVE PACIFIC COUNTRIES: LIGHT MANUFACTURES (L-GOODS) TOTAL SHARE 20.55 per cent CHEMICALS (C-GOODS) TOTAL SI{ARE 46.51 per cent Jap. 0.72 U.S. Jap. 6.81 U.S. 7.99 6.80 "'/ a'e:$ eo s;tL1 a 2Qp s' Aust. "/? A). Can. 4,ll 4,Si'j0.02 ¥ 19.01 b, O 41 ce O.90 e . ,:, ¥.ae S ':) N.Z. 0.11 l. 1 . j',,l ' F:b ,) 9c '',5' ¥ 1:; :.ih s,.'e ' Can. ¥ *t , ) Au5t. ・ 0.17 0.33 5.31 , fs ?f ', h'20 a.(;' t 0.776.27 )h 11Al e' td) 3. 8.40 25.25 3.93 '9 (b 18.04 hF ./ ' 1p ll 85 l.86 0.01 q cP'Y G:, q: a// :: N.Z. ) 0.ll 0.53 5 98 l' 12 I-lITO1'SUBASlll JOURNAL OF EcoNOh'nCS [June in all directions (Fig. 3). Only Japan is in heavy export surplus while the other four countries are in import surplus. Raw materials are as important as L-goods in PAFTA trade, the total share being 20.5 per cent (Fig. 4). The U.S. and Japan are net importing countries while Canada, Australia, and New Zealand net exporting countries. The most significant change during the period of 1958-1965 was the increase of importance In Australian exports to Japan, the U.S., and Canada and the decrease in bilateral trade between the U.S. and Canada. Food is the least irnportant commodity category (11.3 per cent) in PAFTA trade, and oniy Japan is a net importer (Fig'. 5). The most significant change was the decrease in importance of trade between America and Canada. FIG. 4. SHARE IN THE TOTAL INTRA-AREAL FIG.5. SHARE IN THE TOTAL INTRA-AREAL TRADE OF FIVE PACIFIC CoUNTRIES: TRADE OF FIVE PACIFIC COUNTRIES: FOOD (F-GOO_DS) RAW MATERIALS (R-GOODS) TOTAL SHARE 20.45 per cent TOTAL SHARE 11.32. per cent 4;=: _,"22.' U.s:・t "' h-o Jap. . ' l 8.22 t 0.66 0.23 oTl 7 -5.47 : ¥.L B.45 !1 ¥.^(¥. :5* s :j f, :: * a.**a'e ** e 1* ; :; -1 ' *r - ¥ 4.01 c_ ¥:,¥ ) , ¥¥ ,' ". q:; 2 ? 1(¥ ,, t... ¥ *¥ ) ."' 2. LcL ¥ o,06/ ¥ ¥ .* 2. 43..' Aust. ", ". c;F !-_. / . : ':¥; t_. .. 3.28 *o.os of IA・・t. ¥, can,;1017 ', ' t, (2 /'canad e .$ ¥. ', j' I ;a 3.74 o,02/.2.67. 0.53 * .'8.09 :/ ?'¥.0.28 3.ro l 67 ¥ ¥.al 't ? l ¥ ¥a ' , 0.37 .aLt:ob_ ,,f" (b. // "//I':.* ¥.a. Ll . ¥ ) ,z. o.04 N.z.v/ 0.61 : ¥; 0.42 : o,rs ¥ o,17..' The expansion of horizontal trade in manufactured goods can be regarded as the primary acceleror of rapid growth and prosperity of the EEC's intra-bloc trade5 (Table 7). In order to ascertain whether or not similar progress in horizontal trade between the PAFTA countries has been taken place, the degree of horizontal trade6 is calculated (Table 8). 5 Kiyoshi Kojima, "The Pattern of International Trade Among Advanced Countries," Flitotsubashi Journal of Econonubs. June 1964, pp. 24-26. 6 The degree of horizontal trade between two countries for a certain commodity category (denoted by D) is calculated as follows: where country A's imports of commodity h from country B is Ah and country B's imports of the same commodity h from country A is B/ : Ah xIOO, if Ah>B, or D= xIOO, if A,i}<B,t . B, The degree of aggregate horizontal trade (denoted by D) can also be calculated a , the weighted average of D of several commodities by using as weights the percentage ratio of the total of Ah and B!} in the total trade of the two countries, or it is shown as follows: +Bh (if Ah>Bh) D=2AhBh'A,MA+MB Ah' Ah+Bh +1 Bh A+MB (if A,+<Bh) , where MA rel]resents country A's total imports from country B and MB, country B's total imports from country A. The degree of horizontal trade is always less than 100 and the closer it is to 100, the further the horizontal trade is carried out and balanced within the same commodity category or aggregate categories. 13 JAPANPS INTEREST IN THE PAGIFIC TRADE EXPANS10N 1968] TABLE7. DEGREE OF HORlzoNTAL TRADE IN EEC CouNTRIEs upper column,1956−58averages middle column,1960 10wer column,1965 610C2 2 2 3 0=1V1 N2 32 23 ‘1’63 8 59 4 8 ‘1.‘4 81 59 8 56 38 23 ‘1●65 55 84 (b) Tra(ie of each country with EEC as a whole two countries in EEC (a) Trade between each 62●63 21 ‘2D‘4 3 9 ‘2.65 ‘30‘4 100 33 18 25 27 46 3 22 48 6 7 5 42 79 63 61 62 89 24 18 20 58 72 35 27 47 91 90 50 11 16 61・E ‘2・E 63・E ‘4・E 65・E 21 33 13 19 39 63’65 ‘ぺ‘5 50 43 40 67 72 4 22 27 33 48 24 41 24 94 65 18 13 17 48 62 68 73 98 96 90 12 12 14 95 82 71 32 45 79 46 59 96 15 15 16 96 96 32 42 36 35 27 49 50 27 48 95 93 95 59 42 43 70 66 65 48 41 64 77 21 28 72 96 70 59 50 47 99 7 19 10 22 29 15 39 49 73 62 28 32 ・35 27 16 16 21 璃 58 38 70 16 19 21 28 29 39 90 95 80 20 27 34 78 59 53 18 17 64 84 41 18 39 14 L1 55 30 46 73 35 26 97 72 63 98 97 76 72 47 58 43 79 33 25 76 24 22 33 31 33 17 59 63 58 92 53 52 62 44 76 60 40 30 85 89 74 57 67 71 30 39 38 11 15 25 16 45 47 94 78 72 80 69 88 67 81 79 47 96 91 64 18 29 51 76 74 56 31 46 52 84 46 局 73 77 90 18 19 29 37 82 80 96 95 86 86 28 32 67 41 C1 41 51 59 20 52 54 34 59 87 9 『P;T 47 49 57 N N3 53 29 28 97 12 8 71 74 82 45 41 51 56 65 65 44 50 45 54 64 62 34 67 51 94 97 90 12 62 54 44 36 50 98 14 37 26 65 81 72 73 36 39 62 56 69 71 50 55 53 17 36 55 52 94 73 81 83 55 52 76 31 50 64 99 52 68 29 41 28 37 56 43 37 47 34 49 53 50 59 53 53 49 65 55 54 63 32 31 49 36 34 47 50 55 54 46 48 58 72 74 74 43 47 66 59 59 69 43 49 54 46 29 40 15 60 32 33 35 39 30 27 43 45 60 49 60 33 31 36 43 44 48 26 16 15 58 60 62 31 69 32 30 34 63 66 63 62 75 45 24 25 L 48 32 44 56 32 44 69 59 51 47 77 81 70 68 52 55 44 83 42 35 77 35 40 64 67 59 68 46 52 66 52 71 53 43 77 82 76 55 65 67 C 48 67 70 28 49 38 29 51 47 51 58 89 86 81 81 34 42 46 48 60 72 77 89 79 51 80 63 69 58 22 31 50 58 77 47 46 62 36 47 54 48 58 62 37 43 65 46 38 50 51 61 65 69 56 49 49 66 76 73 79 27 26 50 45 53 61 47 53 52 54 56 66 74 80 77 51 L十C 57 58 67 42 53 59 C2 23 99 35 67 13 28 42 33 11 35 42 21 55 41 23 48 60 40 82 36 71 40 52 64 42 47 59 54 42 50 41 43 Note:‘1=WestGermany,‘2=France,‘3=Italy,04ニBelgium and Luxemburg,‘5=Netherland, EニEEC.Reproduced from Kiyoshi Kojima,“The Pattem of Intemational Trade Among Advanced Countries,” H露o‘5μδ∬h∫Jo郡η1‘zJげEヒon(㎜‘‘5,June 1964,PP.25−26,for 1956−58and 1960. O,日 ①.oo一 O.oD αo.コ 一.㎝N 卜.額 卜,雪 一.oっH H.q eq.コ oo.一N 一.NH αo.oうH 寸.雪 oう.一 〇.一 oo,雲 αっ.萬 oっ.一 〇〇.O O.Noつ O.oうoう 頃.oうN 一.①oっ .ON 卜.卜寸 励.①一 〇.一N 寸.〇一 〇.Neq oq.曾 ①.oっN O.〇一 〇.ト一 寸.ON 一.Ooつ ゆ.O oっ.卜H N.φう鴫 卜.Ooo 卜.oっで O,ト一 oっ.自 卜.一N N.qoう O.卜N O.αo寸 門譜 O.〇一 〇っ.卜 oっ,〇一 αo。寸 一.oっ ト.σう O.㎝N O.O 一.︸N 一,ト一 oo。OO O.紹 O.頃oう N,のト N.HN oo.器 O.O N.N oo.H 一.O oっ.寸マ O.等 卜.卜寸 eq.守 O.寸マ ト.ON oっ.O寸 O.Nゆ O。ゆ寸 O.oq寸 H.酪 oD.OO 卜.Ooう cq.蕊 O.O頃 一.Ooう マ.卜O oq.詰 O.Ooo O。2 oD.譜 ㊦.oうO ゆ.αDO O.oう寸 N.Ooo 寸.話 O.O卜 oう.O卜 O.OO αD,oうoっ oo.Oの O.O寸 寸.O寸 一.Oマ 一.αっト O.Oゆ o◎.OO ・oQ.寸寸 oq.oうoう O.①一 一.oうO 寸−ゆト oう,OH 鴫,O 一.H卜 O。Ooo oう.H寸 一.卜寸 O.寸αo O oう.O ㎝.O O O の.曾 O,Ooo O O ゆ。O 寸。OH 嶋.畑 oQ.寸O ︾ O。ゆ 卜︾ oo.oo一 oう.O ㎝.O oう.N一 αo.Ooっ oo,卜 O.oo <↑愛餌”∼ oo.卜 ①.O N.自 O.oう㎝ ①.oう 一.N O.oう O.一 oD.一 寸.O oっ.賃 oo,〇一 cq.O O.N αo.O 寸.卜 O.曾 oo.爵 一.O O 寸.寸 N.㎝ e“.oう ①.O O.O ①.鴫 卜.爲 O.Ooっ 一.一 〇う.O 瞬,寸 oっ,寸O ①.灯 oo.卜 O.曾 O。oう寸 oっ.αDαo ㎝,卜O oD.oう oo.寸 騨.eqO N.等 ①.oうの 寸,等 αD.昏 O.ON O.O卜 N.寸O 一.NH oう.卜H O.ooO O.oD一 ㎝.oo 卜.oりoつ 一.OO N,oうで O.oooっ ①.㎝一 H.寸 寸,ゆ O.寸一 ㎝.O O.NH oっ.αo .お O.扁 ゆ。oっ寸 一.ON .唱区謹”9 O︾ ①.一 O.① 卜.Ooう 、囲田一雪<ー、 OO.N O.寸 マ.一 .−竃冠㊤Nきo乞”魎 ON.cq oo.oD 寸.薯 O,〇一 〇.oo一 ①.寸 H.㊦一 oう.一 〇〇.寸 一.O oo,oう oD。一 寸,一 一。O oQ.N 卜.ON oう.Oり 寸.cq寸 N.卜αo O︾マ O.Ooっ O十q 、<のP”唱 oっ.旨 嶋,爲 O.N寸 寸.Neq 、。啓で胃δ”嶋 O.oo O.oう一 寸.O頃 O.臼 心.唱 恥.卜H 卜.O寸 N.oDO O.αDO αD.卜O N。のマ O.O寸 oう.αD寸 卜.NO 門マoう oD.雲 O.αつ 卜.oうO 卜。O卜 N.一〇っ 寸.oDH .トマ O.oう寸 寸.αDO 一.卜O 卜.Oゆ 一.トマ 一。oうゆ O.OO 一.鴫O ①.αoO N.卜寸 ①。蕊 O.OO oo.爲 卜.O寸 N.寅 O.Ooっ oう.O㎝ c“.器 卜.卜 ㎝,Ooつ N.α〇一 O.① O.oっ O.一N αD,卜 寸.ト一 ①,昏 一.OH N.oD寸 り.oう O.N 層.、 一。一 寸,O oっ.OO O.OO 卜.oo① 璽甚 O。一 ト.O 卜.寸O ゆ,N O.一 N.cqH O.σDH O.oっト O.お 勺。唱 ㎝.O N.O oっ.寸卜 O,昏 σD.嶋 O.卜 .一 一.O O.卜 頃.㎝ O.蕊 O.oうoう 卜.㎝oっ ト.oo㊤ N.寸一 〇う.oD一 、N oQ.O 寸.O O.O 一︾O oっ.Ooo の,O H.㎝ Oめoう αD.O① N.O ①。N 頃,卜 O,寸N oq.O O 一.oう O.oD O.誌 oq.O① O.αDN O.㎝oD 9。心 O寸O.O 一.卜O N.oooう O O O,NO 卜,寸oつ O O 、.唱 O.卜H O,oq一 、.心 H.oり一 一.一一 の。O O oっ,一 〇,oう oo,oう㎝ O O.① 寸.一 卜.一 ︾.一 一.曽 N.〇一 O。oうH マ,自 頃,Ooo O.①N N.ON 寸。NN O O O O O O Ooo.O O O O.O O.N一 O.ON 卜、自 oう。萬 oう.Oマ O.ON O.NN 一.O ①.一 O.oo Qう.Qう N.O 卜︾ 卜.〇一 頃.N 寸.oo O.O N.O oっ.O O.O寸 卜.oo寸 O O N.〇 一.寸 oう.αっN ①.oDO O O oD.O oっ.O O.①N 卜.自 O O 卜.OH O.N O O O.①一 〇.肉 O O 勉.心 O.寸N N.寸一 O O 働・唱 O O 勉・9 N.OO oう.一寸 、.9 O.Noo り.ON \も 一,〇 一.O 、4 N,H N.O 、も 一。H 寸.O 、も q O ≧ 属 ﹄凸q ︻ 賎 ご σ 岬 4 だQ ぞ 渇 だ oう の㊤三暮80乞も邸㊤8①信8①鴛貞︵超︶ の国国﹄Z⇒OQ Q一﹄Qぐ山呂国∩<餌﹄■<﹄しzON一酬δ頃﹄○国国餌O国∩.oo国■oo<↑ 。DO曾.=目三8おa5 08H.唱ε28おき〇一 <↑臣山雨3昏一昌8看器︸o①聴自︵ρ︶ ■、 [June HITOTSUBASHl JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 14 1968] JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 15 i. The aggregate degree of horizontal trade within PAFTA for all commodities, DT, m 1965, was high in the case of the U.S. and Canada, 54.8 and 50.3 respectively, while that of Japan (24.1), Australia (20.4) and New Zealand (13.8) was low. In bilateral trade, Dr was high only in the Arnerican-Canadian trade (47.2) and low in all other bilateral trading, spread- ing from 30.5 to 5.2. The higher figures compare well with intra-areal trade in the EEC which, however, has no lower degree even in bilateral trade. ii. In the EEC, the degree of horizontal trade has rapidly increased in general from 1956-58 and 1965 (Table 7). In PAFTA trade, the degree has increased from 1958 to 1965 in bilateral trade among the U.S.. Canada and Japan, while it has decreased in Australia- PAFTA, Australia-America, New Zealand-PAFTA, New Zealand-Canada, and New ZealandJapan trade. iii. In the degree of horizontal trade by the commodity (D), the higher figures and/or those which show the most significant increase are to be found in heavy manufactures and chemicals (CI and C2) among the trade of the U.S., Canada and Japan; for example, in Cgoods it has increased from 22 in 1958 to 43 in 1965 in American-Canadian trade, from 22 to 54 in American-Japanese trade, and from 43 to 69 in Canadian-Japanese trade. These higher degrees of horizontal trade in heavy manufactures and chemicals are equivalent to those in EEC. The trade of Australia and New Zealaned in this commodity category is low and decreasing in the degree of horizontal trade with other PAFTA countries, iv. Higher degrees of horizontal trade in raw materials (R-goods) are shown in the trade of America-Canada, Arnerica-Australia, Canada-Australia, Canada-New Zealand, and Australia- New Zealand. The promotion of horizontal trade in raw materials between the PAFTA countries, except Japan, would be fruitful. In food (F-goods), horizontal trade has not progressed except in the trade of America-Canada and Australia-New Zealand. In short, horizontal trade between PAFTA countries, with the exception of AmericanCanadian trade, is not well developed relative to that of the EEC. This would suggest us that th re is a plenty of room to expand PAFTA trade through the promotion of horizontal trade, particularly in heavy manufactures and chemicals, and raw meterials as well. 4. Summary The analysis of recent trends in the Pacific trade suggests to us, first, that trade between the five Pacific countries (USA, Canada, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand) has been growing rapidly, and interdependence has intensified. This provides a foundation for moving towards closer economic co-operation and, perhaps, integration. Secondly, although extended Pacific trade had the same scale as European trade in 1958, the latter has gone ahead of the former since then. This suggests a need of closer economic co-operation in the extended Pacific region which possesses huge potential for economic development. Thirdly, the growth centres of the PAFTA trade have been Japan, Australia and U.S.A., while Canada and New Zealand have been lagging behind. Heavy manufactures and chemicals, as well as sophisticated light manufactures, have been leading sectors in trade expansion, while trade in primary produce and traditional light manufactures has been relatively stagnant. Differences by commodity in the growth of trade has a close relation to the growth rate of each country's trade. These trends suggest the main policy targets for further expansion of the Pacific trade. 111TOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 16 [ June III. Static Effects of PAFTA The formation of a Pacific Free Trade Area would, 'in fact, bring about more comprehensive trade liberalization amongst participating countries, with the elimination of tariffs on a substantial proportion on their commodity trade, and would result in a larger trade expansion than is possible through tariff reductions of the Kennedy Round type. Complete regional trade liberalization would appear to have considerable advantages over partial trade liberalization in world markets. This is especially true if, as is most probable, another major round of global tariff reductions is not feasible within the next ten or twenty years. In that event, the formation of PAFTA would seem an effective alternative for mutual trade expansion among the five advanced Pacific countries. 1 . Effects of Tanff Elilnination in PAFTA Here an attempt is made to estimate the impact of the elimination of tariff upon the five Pacific countries which might constitute a Pacific Free Trade Area, on the basis of 1965 trade figures. The method of the estimation is the same as that used in the author's former paperT based on the 1963 trade figures. The impact effect of Pacific tariff elimination would be to increase trade by $5,000 million. This represents an expansion of 28 per cent on intra-areal trade, or 10.3 per cent on Pacific country exports to, and 11.9 per cent on imports from the whole world. In other words, there would be significant trade expansion (Table 9).s The gains from tariff elimination would not be equally distributed amongst the five Pacific countries involved. Japan's exports would increase by $1,740 million, or 56 per cent on her total exports to PAFTA countries, and her imports would increase by $430 million, or 14.7 per cent on her total imports from PAFTA countries. Japan's trade balance with the Pacific, which was roughly in equilibrium in 1965, would consequently improve by $1,310 million. United States' exports would increase by $2,300 million, or 27.9 per cent, and imports by $-2,280 million, or 30.1 per cent, and the favourable balance in United States' trade with the Pacific, of about $850 million in 1965, would be preserved. On the other hand, imports would rise more rapidly than exports for the remaining three countries. Canada's exports would increase by $855 million but her imports would rise by $1,480 million; Australia's exports would increase by $65 million, whereas her imports would rise by $650 million; and New Zealand's exports would grow by $22 million, whilst her imports would rise by $140 million. The differential pattern of gains depends principally upon whether the country's exports are more or less heavily concentrated in manufactures, and suggests a need for fostering further industrialization in Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. Indeed, the pursuit of this objective would be facilitated through the dynamic effects of establishing a larger and completely free 7 Kiyoshi Kojima, "A Pacific Economic Community and Asian Developing Countries," Hitotsubashi Jour'2al of F conomics, June 1966, pp. 23-26. 8 It was estimated that the increase would be $ 3,183 million or 23 per cent of the total intra-area trade in 1963 (Kiyoshi Kojima, ibid., pp. 23-24). A greater increase in 1965 than in 1963 is due to the faster expansion in manufactured trade than in trade of primary products during that period. 19681 JAPAN’S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 17 TABLE9. STAT正c EFFEcTs OF THE FORMATloN oF PAFTA (a) Value of Increase(million dollars) base year=1965 α USA α. USA 4X 一 4M ∠∫x一∠ルf ∠X Canada ∠M ∠X一∠M Australia ∠M 一613.1 17.2 一 75.9 一 75.9 404.4 17.2 4X 23.6 4M 一 1,457.5 1,053.1 426.3 一402.7 一55.9 一 一 一 426.3 23.6 402.7 39.5 2,301.7 10.5 2,283.2 55.9 18.5 7.2 一39.3 1,480.8 7.1 一625.4 33.0 1,743.1 169.1 29.5 1,312.4 一 33.2 39.3 176.7 7.6 216.2 一7.1 一 一208.6 3.4 33.0 一29.6 855.4 0.1 7.6 39.5 Paci6c Countries 66.4 一 8.1 25.1 8.1 10.5 66.4 一58.7 58.7 7.2 4X ∠ルf 4X一〃レf Paci6C Countries 791.5 1,404.6 一1,053。1 0.1 N,Z. 613.1 4X−4ルf イX−4ル1 θ. 一 404.4 1,457.5 8 N.Z。 0.2 4, Japan 一 791.5 4 Austraha 3.5 4X ‘. 1,404.6 6 Japan 0.2 み. δ Canada 一 33.2 一25.1 一 一 ∠X 430.7 64.5 650.6 一586.1 22.1 139.7 一117.6 4,986.8 X 18,021.7 (b) Rate of Increase(%)in trade due to the ElimlnatiQn of Taτiffs ロ USA α. USA ム。 Canada 6。Japan 4. Australia 4X/X ルfノルf ∠X/X M1ル1 4×1× M/M 4×1X ルfμ耀 o. N.Z. 4×1× M1ハ4 Pacific Countries 4X!X わ Canada 7.24 61.48 8.56 53.14 4 Australia β N.Z. Countries 53.13 27.92 19.85 61.48 17.03 58,59 7.24 5,86 26.06 19.85 Japan 26.06 17.03 58.59 ご 35.43 35.43 0.44 0.94 20.95 0.44 50.25 5.86 29.79 29.79 1,37 1.37 61.48 6。85 54,17 8.56 20.95 0.94 54.17 7.02 Paci丘c 30,10 16。74 26.17 55.97 14.69 17.13 5.79 18.95 53,32 18。95 9.76 17.13 33.77 27.67 18 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF EcoNoMlcs [June regional market, and through the freer movement of capital, technical know-how, and managerial skills among member countries. The most important fact to be noted, however, is that the expansion of intra-areal trade would be larger if the five countries could effect tariff elimination.9 As shown in Table 10, in terms of intra-areal trade in 1965, the increase of trade in food and raw materials would be limited (4.5 per cent and 2.0 per cent respectively) while that of light manufactures as well as heavy manufactures and chemicals would be considerable (40.8 per cent and 39.5 per cent respectively). This is also true for each country. These results are as might be expected since existing tariffs and elasticities of demand are low for primary products and high for manufactures. Thus, the elimination of tariffs would promote trade in manufactures of the area as a whole and bilateral horizontal trade, but it would not stimulate to the same degree trade in primary products. These differences result from a variety of effects in each country along the lines mentioned above. TABLE lO. STATIC EFFECTS OF PAFTA BY COMMODITY GROUPS 9 Trade diversion effects are not estimated here. If these are included, the expansion of PAFTA trade would be much larger than our estimates show. 1968] JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 19 How the trade balance between each pair of countries would change is also shown in Table 9. Japan would improve her trade balance with all four countries in the area; the United States would do the same with three countries, except Japan; Canada's trade balance would deteriorate with the United States and Japan, while improving with Australia and New Zealand; Australia's would deteriorate with three countries, except New Zealand; and New Zealand s would detenorate w th all four countnes These results as mentioned already, depend upon the degree of concentration of exports in manufactures or 'in primary products respectively. In view of close trade ties and greater possibilities for increasing trade through the reduction or elimination of tariffs, a Paciffic Free Trade Area among the United States, Canada, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand offers a target worth studying, although it presents a number of problems which need to be solved before its establishment. The estimation of the effects of trade liberalization makes some of these problems clear: i. Although the establishment of PAFTA would result in a sizable expansion of intra-areal trade as a whole, the distribution of gains between the exporting and the importing countries of manufactured goods would be so unequal that no consensus towards the establishment of the PAFTA would be obtainable. Before its establishment, concerted actions of the PAFTA countries to promote export-oriented industrialization of Canada, Australia, and New Zeaiand would be needed. il. As shown in Table 10, heavy manufactures and chemicals would expand remarkably due to the elimination of tariffs both in exports and imports in all the five Pacific countries, The promotion of horizontal trade within the area in these commodities should be the primary goal sought by the five countries whether through the establishment of PAFTA or through alternative measures. These industries can realize the largest dynamic effects through the enlargement of markets and through the freer movement of capital, technical and managerial know-how beyond national frontiers. These dynamic effects would work more favourably for the relatively small countries which have abundant natural resources. It should be noted that the freer movement of capital in this area is much needed in order to promote horizontal trade in heavy manufactures and chemicals. iii. It is estimated that trade in raw materials will expand by a very small percentage (2.0 per cent in the PAFTA as a whole), but greater potential for expansion of this trade can be expected, particularly in the exports of mineral products from Australia and Canada. Further expansion of heavy and chernical industries in the Pacific region would require a rapid development of trade in raw materials and intermediate goods within the area. The import surplus of Canada, Australia, and New Zealand in heavy manufactures and chemicals would be covered by the export surplus from them in raw materials. In agricultural raw materials, however, room for exporting should be provided to developing countries as far as they can produce them competitively. iv. In the trade of light manufactures, the rate of increase due to liberalization would also be large (40.8 per cent in the PAFTA as a whole), but only Japan would enjoy a net increase in exports. Requests for protection of these light manufacturing industries in the U.S., Canada, Australia and New Zealand, mainly for the purpose of maintaining full employment, are so strong at this stage that to abolish trade barriers in this sector would encounter a number of difficulties. Moreover, all PAFTA countries ought to provide free access for developing countries' products of this type. How to foster structural adjustment in this 20 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF EcoNoMlcs [June sector for the five Pacific countries as a whole by taking into consideration the expansion of trade with developing countries in Asia and Latin America would be an important but difficult problem. v. The elimination of tariffs in itself would not change greatly trade in foodstuffs (expected increase being limited to 4.5 per cent), since a number of non-tariff restrictions exist either openly or covertly. Protectionism for agriculture is unreasonably strong, especially in Japan and the United States. Should these protectionist attitudes be rationalized, however, PAFTA trade in food offers much scope for expansion through mutual readjustment. Here, too, attention should be paid to the interests of developing countries. Thus, the five Pacific countries should take measures to expand production and trade of heavy manufactures and chemicals as well as raw materials, on the one hand, and on the other, measures to readjust production and trade of light manufactures and food. Also they have to take into consideration readjustments for increasing trade with developing countries in Asia and Latin America. It might be best to concentrate on the expansion of production and trade in heavy manufactures, chemicals, and raw materials and refrain from pushing the abolition of protectionism in light manufacturing and agriculture, as a first step towards wider Pacific integ'ration. If the expansion of growing sectors is sufiiciently large and rapid, readjustments in the lagging sectors will follow smoothly without so much trouble. For this reason, the sectoral free trade approach has much to recommend it as a first step. In order to expand harmonious production and horizontal trade in these growth sectors within the Pacific area, the elimination of tariffs should work effectively but it alone will not be enough, and a supplementary measures will be required. The free movement of capital and provision of larger markets or, in other words, the dynamic effects of economic integration should be promoted specifically. 2. Effects of Global Tanff Reductions It is beyond our capacity for the time being, although admittedly very important, to estimate rigorously the effects of the Kennedy Round negotiations concluded in June 1967. Here a very rough estimation is attempted in order to show that even the largest global tariff reduction of the Kennedy Round scale would bring about a much smaller expansion of trade for the five Pacific countries than the establishment of the PAFTA. In making this estimate, it is assumed, first, that the elasticity of imports (and exports) with regard to the reduction of tariff is the same as what adopted for each country's trade with the l)AFTA. Secondly, the rate of tariff reductions was 100 per cent in the case of PAFTA, while it is assumed here to be 25 per cent for food, 30 per cent for light manufactures, and 35 per cent both for raw materials and for heavy manufactures and chemicals, for the Kennedy Round negotiations. Thirdly, it is assumed that all the countries in Europe, i.e., the United Kingdom, EEC and other Western Europe, reduce tariffs. Because of these assumptions, the estimation would result in an over-valuation of the actual effects of the Kennedy Round tariff reductions. Our estimates indicate the maximum effect of the global tariff reductions which are likely to be realized. Results of the estimation are shown in Table 11. Firstly, it should be noted that the rate of increase in trade due to tariff reductions is far larger in the case of the formation of PAFTA than in the case of the Kennedy Round. In the former case, the total intra-areal trade of the five Pacific countries in 1965 would increase 1968] JAPAN'S lNTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 21 TABLE 11. COMPARISON OF STATIC EFFECTS OF PAFTA AND THE KENNEDY RoUND (*) PAFTA (b) Kennedy Round by 10.3 per cent and 11.9 per cent respectively for total exports to and imports from the world, while in the latter case by 5.5 per centlo and 7.7 per cent respectively. This suggests to us that a complete regional trade liberalization would be better than partial free trade in respect of the world market for the five Pacific countries as a whole and for each of them. Secondly, balance of payments effects too would be more advantageous in the case of lo The rate of increase in a country's exports is proportional to (a) the rate of tariff reductions and (b) the coverage of area which reduces tariffs for the country's exports. Let rF and rG stand for the rate of tariff reductions in the case of free trade area and of global negotiation respectively, and XF and XG for the share in a country's total exports to the free trade area and to the countries which reduce tariffs outside the free trade area in global negotiation respectively. Then, according as xF/(xF+xG) is greater than, or equal to, or smaller than rGlrF, the increase of a country's exports in the case of free trade area is greater than, or equal to, or smaller than that in the case of global tariff reductions. For the five Pacific countries taken together, in 1965, xF=0.37, xG=0.28 and xFf(xF+xa)=0.57. This is greater than 1-G/1'F=0.3/1, and therefore, the establishment of PAFTA would bring about a greater gain of ex. ports than in the globa] tariff reductions of the Kennedy Round sca]e. 22 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS Uune PAFTA than in the case of global tariff reductions. In the former case, the balance of increments between exports and imports would be zero for the five Pacific countries taken together, while it would be in deficit by $600 million in the latter case. For each country, it may be better to compare in both cases the ratio of imbalance to the sum of incremental exports and imports. The ratio would be 60.4 per cent in the case of PAFTA and 45.4 per cent in the case of global tariff reductions for Japan, O.4 per cent and -7.2 per cent for the U.S., -26.8 per cent and -27.6 per cent for Canada, -82.0 per cent and -85.4 per cent for Australia, and -72.7 per cent and -73.9 per cent for New Zealand. These disadvantageous trade balance effects in the case of global tariff reductions are due to the fact that a group of countries (i,e., developing countries and socialist countries) does not reduce tariffs but is allowed a "free ride" on the Pacufic countrres tanff reductions. The more favourable effects of establishing PAFTA as compared with global tariff reductions should be closely noted by the five Pacific countries, particularly in view of the prospect that another global negotiation of tariff reductions as large as the Kennedy Round scale wou]d not take place in the coming ten to twenty years. 3. The Choice for Japan The best choice for Japan is to expand and free mutual trade with every trading region. The present stage of her industrialization, her dual pattern of trade with developed and developing countries, and her geographical location dictate such a choice.11 However, if a further global tariff reduction is not expected to be feasible in the near future and if, moreover, the com- partmentalization of world trade is promoted further, it would be a serious concern for Japan to devise measures for expanding trade on an assured basis through establishing the Pacific Free Trade Area or some other alternative, The establishment of PAFTA would bring the largest gain to Japan among the five Pacific countries. Japan's exports would increase by $1,740 million or 20.6 per cent of her total exports and her balance of trade with area would improve by $1,310 million. These gains would be far greater than in the case of global tariff reductions of the Kennedy Round scale which would increase Japan's exports by 8.8 per cent. The big gains for Japan from the establishment of PAFTA derive, firstly, from the fact that Japari's exports depend as much as 37 per cent upon the PAFTA markets. European markets are not important (13 per cent) for Japan. Secondly, about 95 per cent of Japan's exports to other Pacific countries are manufactures which would enioy a greater expansion from trade liberalization, while about 71 per cent of Japan's imports are primary products, which would not increase very much in consequence of tariff reductions. When the time comes for Japan to consider economic integration, it should be a Pacific Free Trade Area. Japan is destined by geography to participate in political arrangements in the Pacific rather than in Europe. Moreover, economic integration without the United States, whose importance for Japan's market is as large as 30 per cent, offers lesser incentive for Japan to join. Thus, Japan would benefit from the establishment of PAFTA, or from some other alternative, through the cheaper import of raw materials and other primary products, the expansion 11 Kiyoshi Kojima, "Trade Arrangements among Industrial Countries: Effects on Japan," in Bela Balassa, Studies in 'rradc Libe'-alization. The Johns Hopkins Press, Baltimore, 1967, p. 211. JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE ExpANsloN 1 9 68] 23 of her exports of light manufactures, and the promotion of horizontal trade in heavy manufactures and chemicals. The formation of PAFTA or some other alternative for economic co-operation among the five Pacific countries is desired by Japan for another reason. Collective measures by the group are especially desirable for assisting economic development and trade growth in Southeast Asian countries. Asian markets are very important for Japan relative to for other Pacific advanced countries. The share of Asia (excluding Mainland China) in Japan's total exports is as large as 26 per cent, though it has been decreasing. Japan cannot disregard the interests of developing countries, especially in South and Southeast Asia, and the same applies to the United States vis- -vis Latin America. The question is often raised: should Japan rely on the rapidly increasing but competitive markets in developed countries, or on the complementary but more slowly expanding markets in developing countries? She has, in fact, to expand trade in both directions. If the five Pacific countries were to establish PAFTA, they should welcome as associated members those developing countries in Asia and Latin America who wish to join. Or, they might provide general preferential tariffsl2 in favour of the developing countries. Moreover, the five Pacific countries should provide assistance more efficiently and on a larger scale to foster structural adjustment in their own industries in order to open wider markets for devel- oping countries products. Concerted policy measures among the flve Pacific countries are urgently required. In this context, Japan's attitude towards Mainlaind China present a problem. Political, military, and ideological troubles aside, however, it is obvious that main supply sources of natural resources and profitable markets for Japan are not the Asian mainland but the extended Pacific region, Although it seems to be quite beneficial for Japan to establish the Pacific Free Trade Area, there is hesitation and/or caution in Japan about stepping out in that direction. One of the reasons for hesitation is heavy protectionism for agriculture which needs time to be rationalized. The other is fear about the penetration and domination of American capital. These difficulties and worries should be remedied from a wider viewpoint of economic cooperation within the extended Pacific region. IV. Closer Pacific Trade Partnership At this stage, the PAFTA proposal seems premature, unless there is some further unforeseen disturbance in the free world economy. It is as yet neither economically nor politically feasible. Firstly, American interests are presently worldwide and the United States could not participate readily either in a Pacific or a European regional grouping. For the moment, the United States appears committed to a global non-discriminatory approach to freer trade.13 12 See. Kiyoshi Kojima, "General Preferences to Developing Countries: A Japanese Assessment," Tl,e U,iited Mtilayan Banking Corporation Econolnic Review, forthcoming. Is Cf. John W. Evans, U.S. Trede Policy. New Legislation for the Next Round, Council on Foreign Relations, 1967. Alfred C. Neal, "Economic Necessities and Atlantlc Communities," Foret n Affairs, Jul 1967. William Diebold, Jr., "Doubts about Atlantic Free Trade," The Round Thble October 1967. Wi liam Dlebold, Jr., "Future Negotraung Issues and Polrcres m Forelgn Trade, Issues alid Objecttves of U.S. Foreign 'rrade Policy, Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States. September, 1967. ・ ・ ・ ・ ・ ・ ・ ・ ,, ' ・ - 24 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS [June Secondly, the five Pacific countries still lack the solidarity and degree of integration that wou]d be necessary for dispensing with protective measures for the main sectors of their economies involved in regional trade-the labour-intensive industries in some countries, the agricultural and pastoral industries in other countries.14 Thirdly, the static gains from complete trade liberalization would differ widely from one country to another because of the disparity in stages of industrialization within the region. However, the realization of PAFTA might be precipitated by a shock w_hich came from outside the area. Greater European integration between EEC and EFTA could produce an "inward looking" Europe whereupon the United States might well find closer integration in the Pacific desirable and necessary, Should the United Kingdom fail again to join the EEC, she might probe the establishment of a North Atlantic Free Trade Area with the United States and Canada.15 In the case, Japan, Australia and New Zealand might have to consider seriously their own integration. Moreover, PAFTA and NAFTA might be linked together through the U.S. and Canada which would belong to the two free trade areas.16 Economic integration in the Pacific should be a free trade area instead of a customs union or political union. A free trade area arrangement would have advantages over the alternatives from several points of view: it is consistent with the rules of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade; it preserves the autonomy of members with respect to their tariff policies vis- -vis non-participants; and it is a purely commercial arrangement, carrying no obligation for eventual political federation or union.17 Whether or not a free trade area can ultimately be established, the five advanced Pacific countries should now set about establishing closer and more profitable trade partnerships with each other. To date, the United States has tended to look toward the possibility of ultimately 'going in with Europe', and has tended to neglect the Pacific region. The flow of financial resources and direct investment from America to Pacific basin countries, including Asian and Latin American countries, has lagged behind that going to Europe,18 The Pacific, Asian, and 14 A comment against PAFTA is presented by H.W. Arndt, "PAFTA An Australlan Assessment " Intereconomics Hamburg, October 1967, to which there is a reply by K yoshi Kojima, "A Paclfic Free Trade Area: econsidered," ibid., March 1968. 15 Maxwell Stamp Associates, The Free Trede Area Option, Opportunityfor B,-itain, the Atlantic Trade Study, London, 1967. Theodore Geiger and Sperry Lea, "The Free Trade Area Concept as Applied to the United States," Looking Aheed, National Planning Association, Washington, October 1967. 16 If NAFTA is instituted among the U.S., Canada and Britain while PAFTA is not, Japan should join the former since otherwise she would suffer from large-scale trade diversion. It is estimated that "the UK would capture about 10 per cent of Japanese trade (say about $ 225 mil]ion) in North American markets, if Japan were not in NAFTA." (Maxwell Stamp Associates. The Free T1lade Area Option, ibid. , p. 44). Since the NAFTA proposal aims at freeing of non-agricultural trade, Australia and New Zealand would be less interested in joining (Ibid., p. 38). Both for NAFTA and PAFTA, a crucial question is: "Would the Americans accept the free trade area concept of a new Grand Design?" (Ibid., p. 78). 17 See, Harry G. Johnson, "Proposals for a North Atlantic Free Trade Area," an address to the European- Atlantic Group, 6 March 1967, pp. 4-5. Canadian-American Committee, A Caneda-U.S. Free Trede Arrangement, Survey of Possible Characteristics, October 1963. Ditto., A Possible Plan for Caneda-U.S. Free Trede /lrea. A Staff Report, February 1965. Ditto. A New Trede Strategy for Ca'leda a'td the United States, May 1966. 18 The financial resources flows from developed to developing countries in 1964 were $ 8.51 per capita for Africa, while they were $ 3.92 for Latin America, $ 2.85 for South Asia, and $ 3.88 for Far East, The last one was, however, very small if aid to South Vietnum is excluded. (OECD, Geographical Distribution of Financlal Flows to Less Develo d Countries, 1966.) The U.S. Direct foreign investments, amounting to $ 49,328 million at the end of 1965, have directed mainly to Canada (30.9 per cent), EEC (12.8 per cent) and other Europe (15.6 per cent), while Oceania (3.7 per cent) and Japan (1.4 per cent) have benefited not only very limited amount but also in slower increase relative to Europe (US Department of Commerce, Survey tf Cunient Business, September 1967). 1968] JAPAN'S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 25 Latin American region has a huge potential for trade growth and development compared with Europe, and it should be looked at more closely. Studies and proposals about Pacific trade expansion have been quite limited. However, recently a movement in this direction has been initiated. The Canada-United States Automo- tive Agreement has taken effect from January 1965. This should be given much attention as a pioneer of selective industrial integration,19 The Australia-New Zealand Free Trade Agree- ment began in January 1966.20 The Pacific Basin Economic Co-operation Committee was established among business circles of the five Pacific countries in April 1967; and a number of bilateral co-operative activities have been promoted in business circles. It should be noted also that Mr. Takeo Miki, Japan's Foreign Minister, is keenly interested in promoting economic co-operation in the Pacific and Asian region. Before the establishment of PAFTA, several steps towards closer Pacific economic cooperation might be practicable immediately. Five main objectives suggest themselves: 1. To increase the flow of financial resources from the United States to other Pacific countries, as well as to Asian and Latin American developing countries. 2. ・ To stimulate horizontal trade among the five advanced Pacific countries in heavy manufactures and chemicals and to expand production and trade of raw materials and intermediate goods more efflciently for the region as a whole. 3. To readjust production and trade in agricultural commodities among the five Pacific countries, taking into consideration their relationship with Asian and Latin American developing countries. 4. To readjust production and trade of light manufactures, which are labour intensive, with the aim of providing greater access for Asian and Latin American countries in advanced country markets. . po rcy o 5 To co-ordinate the aid l' f the five advanced Pacific countries towards Asian and Latin American developing countries. Practical steps towards closer Pacific economic co-operation can be taken by strengthening functional, rather than institutional integration, and thus attempting to attain the favourable benefits of a free trade area whilst avoiding the unfavourable impact effects. To realize these objectives, I suggest the initiation of three codes of international behaviour and the formation of two new regional institutions. 1. A code of good conduct in the field of trade policy, under which countries would relinquish the right to raise tariffs or impose other forms of trade restriction,21 and would gradually reduce those trade barriers particularly on the import of agricultural products and labour intensive light manufactures, should be promulgated. 2. A code of overseas investment to promote mutual investment among the five advanced Pacific countries, most effectively from the United States, and to foster the activity of joint ventures is much needed to promote trade expansion, especially horizontal trade expansion 19 See, Sperry Lea, "Free Trade by Sectors," NPA, Looking Aheed, September 1966. 2Q F.W. Holmes, "Australia and New Zeal nd in the World Economy," The Ec' onomic Record, March 1967. 21 The assurance against the reimposition of duties in a free trade area wou]d induce enterprises to expand trade and investment abroad . The code of good conduct would reduce uncertainty in international trade and be a partial substitute for the formation of free trade area. See. Bela Balassa, Trade I_iberalizat 'on A1'10n I d t " I Count,' s Council on Foreign Relations 1967 pl" 160-1(;1. l g n uslra I ., , , 26 HITOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF Eco) 'oMlcs [June In heavy manufactures 22 and for the development of the vast mmeral resources of the Pacific region. A code which minimises the fear of American capital domination and maximises protection for America's balance of payments would greatly facilitate overseas investment and the better allocation of regional resources. 3. A code of aid and trede policies towards associated developing countries is also required, so that Asian and Latin American countries might enjoy the benefits of larger markets for their agricultural products and light manufactures. The flow of developmental aid must be increased, appropriate aid projects selected, and domestic industrial structures adjusted to meet the legitimate trade needs of affiliated less developed countries.2s An Organization for Paclfic Trade and Development (OPTAD) should be established in order to give effect to these codes of international behaviour. Its main features would be similar to those of the OECD, and it could be structured in the same way, with three committees on trade, investment, and aid.24 Further, a Paclfic Bankfo' Investment and Settlenrent would be established with the aim of facilitating investment and settlement within the Pacific. Asian, and Latin American region, and equipped with a mechanism for preventing the drainage of gold from the United States.25 22 N.P.G. Elkan suggests an interesting scheme for promoting horizontal trade in his article, "How to Beat Backwash: The Case for Customs-Drawback Unions," Economic Journal, March 1965. His plan may be applicable to trade between small economies like Australia and New Zealand but would be too cumbersome to work in wider markets. It seems to me that horizontal trade would be fostered most efficiently through the expansion of joint ventures and other private capital's activities. 2B See, Kiyoshi Kojima, "A Proposal for International Aid," The Developing Econolnies, December 1964. Ditto, "Japan's Role in Asian Agricultural Development," The Japan Quarterly, April-June, 1967. 24 Aid Committee could be set up first because of urgency for increasing aid and trade with developing countries. 25 My own thought was shown in Kiyoshi Kojima, "A Proposal for Increasing International Liquidity," The Oriental Econo'nist, Aug., 1964, which was reviewed in "How Aid Could be Untied," The Econovnist (London). July 25, 1964, pp. 401-402. 27 JAPAN’S INTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 1968】 STATlsTlcAL APPENDDζ: TRADE MATRlx BY CoMMQDITY GRoup(1,000dollars) upper column,1958 middle cQlumn,1963 10wer column,1965 (1) 〈71−goods to xports from SA 1,713 1,357,101 97}018 71,904 ,380,451 ,673,502 130,054 85,993 649,506 5,017 5,798 29,973 22,640 221 957 0 ,154 2,332 ,028 0,299 119,763 23,408 2,816 14,944 一 一 57 42 177 56 455,940 40,154 09,467 12,923 52 43,226 『 一一一 5,533 一 15 2,128,879 ,658,406 一 一一一 301,253 1,181 2,614 16ン126 55,727 21,667 6,113 4,449 0126 10,374 345,540 74,068 31,564 0133 4,829 51 1013 ,12,365 0 0 42,708 57 66 138,222 32,699 16,126 一一一 0 20,740 20,835 00一 240 08 201,312 0133 26,616 69ン236 48,699 57 68 49 9 0681 5,100 Total xports 000 000 16,573 66 18 ther Asia ∫Paci五c C. θ .Z. 0 0 一一一 226 96 42 0 000 9.Other Asia 8,831 6,668 32 1,142 6,653 一一一 57,142 f.Paci丘c C. 73,101 000 6. New Zealand 82,469 0371 000 000 4. Australia 047498 0 0 0681 189 ‘. Japan 111,638 26,584 69,236 48,328 000 000 8,831 5,987 apan 一一一 56,953 ム. Canada 4 ustralia f anada 一一一 α. USA δ α 28 田TOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS 【June (2) ハ尾一goods to 6 α xports from SA anada 一一一 α. USA 12,950 76,358 89,118 32,137 ’σ. New Zealand ∫.Paci丘c C. 6,230 ,722 0,436 22,434 22,174 57,086 8,388 1,827 9,622 1,671 3,460 7,728 67,460 9,124 1,181 2,376 9,226 ,532 ,083 245,573 96,737 28,226 29,439 33,259 351,700 175,633 9,584 61,801 64,050 0,(〕85 17,963 61,037 01,584 359,583 23,456 50,290 165,409 ,047 388,657 ,254 454,635 02,841 927 1,064 382,735 10,777 ,130 ,880 3,805 ,721 ,321 3,840 ,720,225 43,383 1, 881,504 988 318,734 ,183 435,331 1,252 84,886 557 92,355 42,597 675 118,642 7,148 9,035 2,679 2,714 7,588 40,081 0,472 347,933 1,632 246,068 75,797 _ 81,6(巧一 102,746− 76,172 14,363 ,150 ,708 11,475 ,891 ,575 412,011 一 395,924 49,063 43,378 308,9432, 520,664 92,7723, 一 26,817 一 2,517 一 82,497 34,969 77,903 1,898 903,69511,723 669,081 14881 , 231,115 一 5,124 6,0641,250,425 8,7441,330,848 97,129 56,836 6,885 ,476 11,573 828,660 490,040 2,794 一 ﹃一一 542,076 ,687 5,155 991,574 1,669 239,353 一一一 9、Other Asia ,784 ,564 Total xports 2,903 4,146 8,126 一一一 4。 Australia 2,355 8,210 2,161 一一一 73,599 6. Japan ﹃一一 09,832 23,704 4,106 ther Asia 9 ustralia apan 221,831 378,583 み. Canada θ ∫N.Z. Paci丘c C. 4 ‘ (3) ム㌔一goods to xports from δ α SA anada 一一一 α. USA 148,362 7,616 85,963 27,859 94,760 9,921 7,111 1,607 05,921 32,823 8, New Zealand 5,363 6,261 408,192 ∫.Paci丘c C. 3,283 ,606 ,912 2,022 ,871 ,102 154,624 246,273 23,663 136,590 ,189 571,775 ,504 785,643 41,118 70,208 10,721 8,595 3,291 3,857 1,191 348,622 5,011 0,937 158,786 12,167 96,895 10,785 4,981 9,589 4267565 468,726 20,256 206,763 70,609 81,355 455 0 }247 7,586 ,249 497,410 ,013 561,567 0,725 3,324 31,240 8,355 『 ,852 ,695 635 20,618 16,900 5,661 196,413 22,981 01 31,283 71 32,188 ,245 374,625 ,516 417,244 一 53,216− 104,452− 109,553 ,237 ,601 40,299 3,767 0,482 9,342 94,278 40,857 21,397 757,462 ,102,113 一 2,248 265,877 182,486 ,7841,579,545 17,208 ,811 881,644 ,638 一 09,297 88,134 一 9,2271,038,907 5,475 732,460 503,246 9,315 ,441 ,105 3,3041,906,195 ,999,188 ,342,492 『 63,966 68,582 3,162,759 ,315,421 『 一一一 02,536 6,043 5,828 1,541,896 1,740 420,038 9,197 9,619 93,932 42,978 41,826 95,142 Total xports 01,773 65,557 74,750 94,053 1,354 ther Asia 9 ﹃一﹃ 9,0ther Asia 》261 }559 ustralia 一一一 28,683 4. Australia 957 8 ∫N.Z, Paci丘c C. apan 一﹃一 18,571 ‘. Japan 一一一 328,115 δ. Canada ご ‘ 1968] 29 JAPAN’S INTEREST IN THE PAαFIC TRADE EXPANSION (4) ハ7‘一goods to xports from ‘z δ ustralia 8 。Z. 一 291,867− 303,732− 369,724 103,137 13,954 4,316 α. USA み. Canada 4 apan ‘ SA Canada 604,849 − 36,661 − 02,908 一 47,645 97,164 0,805 1,236 ,457,962 ,617,756 10,082 3,768 617 765 619,316 1,020 799,345 41,709 18,016 0,737 1,348 76,029 18,804 81,612 277534 3,676 9,001 17シ144 0 ,456 50,655 23,747 74,247 5,057 0 2,617 一 一 15 2,796 64,426 6,224 44,823 『 111 一 680 ,786 2,321,290 1,906 ,778,559 『 一 379,081 9,982 1,743 1,389 99,392 59,984 264 923 ,694,388 ,778,402 14,423 3,735 10,675 2,136 1,085,567 ,138,190 ,412,743 ﹃一一 91,864 65,898 8,170 0,213 186 ,366 ,319 ﹃一一 160,293 22,601 22,732 96,612 0897 129,821 0 一一一 152 759 50,286 303,860 28,665 370,584 118,849 1,183 6,016 737 4,570 1,625 164 12 64 1,972 0 0 ,524 0 ,524 一一一 9,0ther Asia 130 1,824 618,329 291,867 ∫.Paci丘c C. 0,914 14,630 0 0 o, New Zealand ,433 0640 0 0 ,138 154 3,625 128 1,619 706 1,405,334 ,741 ,624 8,873 1,266 13,424 0 47,659 3,992 5,746 一一一 4. Australia 413,274 Total xports 15,180 95シ070 56 0 ‘. Japan 9 ∫Paci丘c C。Other Asia (5) Z,1−goods to み α xports from 22,596 52,732 65》454 77,092 336 77 44 158 θ. New Zeaiand 11 16 1,084,139 ∫.PaciHc C. ,323 ,082 1,035 ,446 ,515 12 10,489 8,253 6,013 46,524 6,789 48,674 8,234 2,915 8,276 3,811 262,299 2,532 610,621 5,150 688,428 137,181 3,019 723,847 3,453 0,171 3,840 ,905 746,077 ,384 884,211 5,207 471,170 316,931 9,204 725,983 37,640 54,169 0,392 1,139,558 12,731 15,947 3,101 34,564 7,778 30,079 一 8,404− 13,226− 18,650 152,216 21,025 2,802 38,990 10,793 225,826 ,147 5,011 一 0 8,7422,130,471 6,7042,760,926 9,530 586,367陶 6,089 一 460,574 32,258 『 Total xports 2,012,458 ,312,407 ,242,724 875,141 956,139 ,125,168 1,252,261 ,927,510 ,489,186 33,232 5,515 一 9,992 5,597 1,972 4,183,084 ,267,168 一 一﹃一 73,479 70,926 65ン315 24,7681,481,667 7,466 4,963 7,142 ,384 『 ,119 88,236 28,362 5,143 0,017 3,009 560 ,295,101 ,735,582 47,536 60,157 75,503 86,333 ﹃一一 9,0ther Asia 288,792 11,175 157 058 000 ,740 ,442 4,536 3,400 7,546 2,969 2,352 一一一 1,845 4。 Australia 46,799 9,285 1,697 6,308 一一一 372,640 c. Japan 23,423 34,618 一﹃一 709,496 ウ。 Canada ustralla apan 241,657 9 β ∫N.Z. Paci五c C.Other Asia 4 ‘ anada 一一一 4. USA SA 30 H【TOTSUBASHI JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS [June (6) Z,2−goods to xportsfrom δ α SA 一一一 α. USA 93,164 24,988 6,231 7,225 73,985 66,333 52,529 631 972 732 22,078 2,607 353 88,243 90,018 00,522 一一︸ 08,109 49,708 25,436 3,604 3,842 136 ,017 ,305 554 ,113 一 2,312 2,658 0,170 ,253 ,800 183,539 46,069 29,651 49,141 4,028 46,294 3,173 22,044 ,905 1,242 一 一 21 27 99 7,501 9,782 9,472 373,384 137,994 53,833 42,543 94,561 194 89 45 8,488 0,126 一 295 366 ,526 1,570,596 ,167,131 一 一一一 ,475 ,549 9,663 9,030 2,020 2,323 8,274 48,581 46,045 28,224 5,091 4,677 3,296 ,591 ,369 ,549,827 ,228,153 一一一 838 13,586 ,069 867 1,316,137 83,661 20,375 25》310 000 6,766 5,332 3,381 232,841 21 27 99 260,730 一︸一 94,020 32,675 20,491 一一一 ,028 0 0,932 000 0 224 ,373 0131 9,0therAsia 76,353 37,856 000 11 000 ∫.PaciHcC. ,799 ,962 4,721 3,692 37 θ. New Zealand 4,396 》234 ,328 Total xports 9 ∫Paci丘cC。OtherAsla 9,986 5,929 3,071 11,298 292 4. Australia 8 .Z. 2,461 2,835 24,805 143, 876 ﹃一一 ‘. Japan apan 221,543 19,743 ウ. Canada 4 ustralia ‘ anada 一 (7) C1−goods \ t・ 、 xp。rtsfr\ 635,542 930,271 ,171,719 66,489 64,946 63,226 5,019 7,975 6,594 25,177 162 4,032 7,866 9,520 1》798 2,209 6,016 3,028 173 1,149 ,543 ,170 ,213,461 ,875,875 492,702 103,783 21,185 95,434 64,977 86,737 ,936 7,960 14,836 3,320 3,007 8,263 7,324 6,030 8,143 2,061 5,743 0,405 ,343 47,276 26,493 11,755 2,633 ,695 一 ther Asia 6,223 3》654 7,946 1, 2,533 ,273 3,006 458 3,511 7,343 31,434 7,530 0,161 40,648 614,501 160,232 00,280 76,078 93,990 30,188 653,484 994,673 916 ,775 45,458 Total xports 2,250,523 ,998,195 ,789,387 1,174,812 3,841 3,428 ,505,568 ,863,532 77,996 24,575 19,224 262,788 464,315 71,486 38,567 ,163,256 ,139,099 58,571 16,015 129,996 ,261,569 7,381 12,644 10,093 2,175 8,742 1,414,645 02,9682, 229,084 18,4563, 288,257 1,079 9 75,253 61,698 一 2,783 一 353 63 55 484,846 42,363 一 91,112 一 17,104 0,625 4,383 4,036,750 ,878,756 一 一一一 2,420 11,377 ∫Paci丘c C. 一一一 54,285 02,831 65,640 227 ,229 9,682 5,027 θ .Z. 一一一 9。Other Asia 24,126 941 ,707 730,236 ∫,Paci丘c C, 96,804 14,675 16,972 6,701 3,760 0 0 θ. New Zealand 02,269 46,133 ustralia 一一一 4. Australia 487,348 apan 一一一 ‘。 Japan 4 ‘ anada 一一一 み. Canada SA 一一一 α. USA ゐ α JAPAN'S lNTEREST IN THE PACIFIC TRADE EXPANSION 1968] (8) C2-goods Note l. 2. 3. 4. 5. Source: UN, Colnmodity Trede Statistics, Figures are the value of exports from each country. Since figures of Australia for 1965 are not available, exports of other four Pacific countries to Australia are shown as Australian imports , and imports of those countries from Australia are shown as Australian exports. Figures of New Zealand for 1963 cover the period from July 1962 to June 1963. "Other Asia" covers the same countries as shown in the footnote of Table 1. As regards commodity classification, see the text. 31
© Copyright 2024 ExpyDoc