Armed Groups and Militarized Elections Paul Staniland Assistant Professor of Political Science University of Chicago [email protected] DRAFT September 2014 Abstract: Non-state armed groups are often involved in electoral violence, but we know little about the origins or fates of these groups. This article develops an interactive theory of relations between governments and electoral armed groups. Governments assign different political roles to armed groups that reflect their ideological position and electoral value. State strategies flow from these political roles, but groups’ organizational capacity can allow them to resist government efforts to control, destroy, or incorporate them. The interaction of regime political interests and armed group autonomy leads to five distinct government-armed group trajectories, ranging from incorporation to violent conflict. Comparative evidence from militarized elections in Karachi is used to illustrate the validity of the concepts and assess the power of the theory, while also exploring their limits and future research. The argument and findings improve our understanding of the linkages between democracy, civil conflict, and state power. Word Count: 11,653 Acknowledgments: Thanks to Mike Albertus, Laia Balcells, Ahsan Butt, Christopher Clary, Jesse Driscoll, Kristin Fabbe, Laurent Gayer, Morgan Kaplan, Matthew Kocher, Peter Krause, Austin Long, Aila Matanock, Asfandyar Mir, Vipin Narang, Dann Naseemullah, Irfan Nooruddin, Dan Slater, Abbey Steele, Emmanuel Teitelbaum, Monica Toft, Steven Wilkinson, Adam Ziegfeld, and participants in seminars at the Department of Political Science at the National University of Singapore, R. Allan Bennett Lecture Series at the University of Connecticut, and Security, Peace, and Conflict workshop at Duke University for helpful comments on various versions of this paper. Excellent research assistance by Saalika Mela and Jonathan Weatherwax is gratefully acknowledged. 2 In 1984, the Sikh Golden Temple in the Indian state of Punjab was stormed by the Indian Army, Prime Minister Indira Gandhi was assassinated by her Sikh bodyguards, and an insurgency erupted that took tens of thousands of lives over the next decade. At first glance, this seems like just another anti-state rebellion in South Asia. But it actually emerged from a conscious attempt to use violence to win elections by key figures in the ruling Indian National Congress, who had propped up a radical Sikh preacher to splinter a powerful regional party. This electoral strategy exploded out of the government’s control, at huge human cost. Punjab is a particularly dramatic case of electoral militarization run amok, but it points to an important gap in our understanding of electoral violence. Existing research assumes that governments can control non-state armed actors, allowing them to carefully unleash and rein in violence to win elections (Wilkinson 2004, Hafner-Burton et al. 2014). This article shows instead that armed groups can defy, manipulate, or bargain with governments. Rather than assuming topdown control, it advances an interactive theory to explain the varying political relationships between governments and electoral armed groups. The diverse trajectories that these armed actors follow – from being co-opted into the state to turning against the political system – are crucial to explaining patterns of democratization, civil war, and international intervention. Militarized elections are common, ranging from contemporary Pakistan to 1950s Burma to 19th century America. They pose huge challenges to international organizations tasked with facilitating democratization, external interveners trying to keep and build peace, and citizens and politicians caught in the path of violence. In Libya after the overthrow of Muammar el-Qaddafi, the persistence of militias means that elected politicians lead or ally with non-state armed groups, rather than using the state to straightforwardly foster or crack down on violence. This is true beyond Libya. In Iraq, the Philippines, and Lebanon, for 3 instance, armed factions are deeply intertwined with “mainstream” electoral politics. We need new concepts, theories, and evidence to make sense of these political dynamics. This article explains the origins and trajectories of government-electoral armed group relationships. Armed groups occupy different political roles as a result of their ideological position and electoral value. These roles, in turn, shape how governments treat them. But groups are not necessarily pawns of regimes. Instead, they can resist co-optation, repression, or control when they have organizational power autonomous from government patronage. Organizationally dependent groups are purged, incorporated into the ruling party or state, or controlled as proxies of the regime, depending on the group’s political role. Autonomous armed groups, by contrast, resist incorporation and control to become “normalized” actors mixing ballots and bullets or defy suppression and emerge as resilient opponents of state power. The article first introduces two new concepts – militarized elections and electoral armed groups – and identifies why they matter for understanding democratization, civil conflict, and international interventions. It then theorizes the relationships that emerge between governments and electoral armed groups, showing how groups become resilient opponents, incorporated, purged, normalized, or proxies. These trajectories are illustrated with examples from a wide variety of cases. Third, comparative evidence from Karachi’s lethal electoral politics is used to more systematically explore the theory’s explanatory power. This research design leverages over-time and cross-group comparisons within a shared context, revealing strengths and limits of the argument. The theory and evidence help us understand when and how coercion and democratic practice are fused together, creating distinctive forms of armed politics in an era in which elections have spread but violence persists. 4 Militarized Elections and Electoral Armed Groups Violent elections occur with some regularity (Straus and Taylor 2012, Hyde and Marinov 2012). This article focuses on a subset of those elections – electoral environments in which at least two contenders for power use lethal violence and its threat to try to coerce or displace opponents, manipulate voting, and/or intimidate the press and other observers.1 I refer to these as militarized elections. Two dynamics can encourage the emergence of militarized elections. First, regimes that are forced into partial political liberalization, often by international pressures, can sponsor non-state violence as a substitute for direct state repression (Reno 2011, Levitsky and Way 2010, Bekoe 2012, Roessler 2005, Collier 2009). Second, militarized elections can emerge in weakly institutionalized democracies, as politicians restrain coercion against electorally valuable armed groups that represent a political party or important social constituency (Wilkinson 2004, Brass 1997, Snyder 2000).2 Opposition parties can in turn acquire weapons, build armed wings, or cultivate armed actors – such as street gangs and insurgents – to engage in these “armed politics.” Electoral armed groups are the non-state armed actors, linked to either governments or oppositions, involved in militarized elections. They include militias, the armed wings of parties, criminal networks, militant groups, insurgents, and student activist organizations. Government leaders, the international community, and state security forces have received the overwhelming 1 I do not study armed groups that are not involved in trying to win elections, the government forces involved in electoral conflict, elections in which only the state uses violence. These are important areas, but beyond the scope of this article. 2 For more on electoral violence, see Varshney 2002, Roessler 2005, Dunning 2011, Flores and Nooruddin 2012, Brancati and Snyder 2011. 5 bulk of attention in electoral violence research, but the trajectories of electoral armed groups themselves need careful attention. They can influence four important areas of political life. First, the activities of electoral armed groups can allow regimes to evade international strategies for post-conflict democratization (Brancati and Snyder 2012, Nooruddin and Flores 2012, Radin 2012, Paris 2004) and election monitoring (Kelley 2012, Hyde 2011, von Borzyskowski 2014). By claiming that they are not responsible for electoral violence, regimes may limit their vulnerability to international sanctioning while still retaining power. International intervention and democratization policies are often thwarted or manipulated by the violence committed by electoral armed groups. In Iraq, Afghanistan, and Libya, for instance, politicianand party-linked paramilitaries and private armies have posed huge challenges for democratization and stabilization missions. Second, militarized elections can contribute to the onset of civil wars, through two mechanisms. In the first pathway, electoral armed groups may turn against the state or be targeted by it for destruction, leading to internal conflict. The case of the Indian Punjab introduced above is a striking example of this pathway to civil conflict, while Reno (2011) finds in Africa that “the appearance of armed factions associated with past and present governments, conceived in part as instruments to bolster these governments, came to be the principal threat to their security” (Reno 2011, 244). In the second pathway, even when under government control, electoral armed groups can be tools of ethnic cleansing and civilian displacement, operating as the shock troops of regimes when electoral polarization escalates into full-scale conflict (Snyder 2000). These groups add dangerous volatility to already unstable electoral competitions. Third, the long-term fates of electoral armed groups can shape the structure and extent of state power, even in the absence of civil conflict. If governments are able to incorporate or purge 6 these groups, regimes can centralize coercion. This is an important mechanism of state building. Cooperation with independent armed groups, by contrast, can leave certain geographic areas and functional domains under the de facto control of these non-state actors. Complex “topographies” of state power (Boone 2003, Staniland 2012) emerge when state and non-state violence become intertwined in this manner. Fourth, the quality of democracy hinges on the use of violence in the electoral arena. If electoral armed groups operate autonomously, they become power-brokers that control patronage and political mobilization at the point of a gun. If these groups are controlled by the government, they may be used as tools of social control that allow regimes to discipline and co-opt local communities. In both cases, the existence of electoral armed groups can hollow out democratic representation and institutional responsiveness, creating an “armed clientelism” (Eaton 2006). Yet electoral militarization can also have positive consequences for democracy. Violent elections sometimes provide a way of bringing armed factions into the political system by creating incentives to engage with formal electoral processes, rather than opposing them from the outside (Reno 2011). Such elections may even give voice to previously excluded social sectors, facilitating democratization from below (Wood 2000). Electoral armed groups can bargain with regimes for political concessions, creating an unorthodox and double-edged, but important, pathway of electoral participation. Theorizing Armed Group Trajectories Despite these high stakes, existing research has not explored where electoral armed groups come from or what trajectories they take over time. This oversight flows from two assumptions: first, that non-state violence is manipulated by ruling politicians simply trying to 7 win elections and, second, that when violence has served its electoral purpose, politicians can shut down armed groups (Wilkinson 2004, Hafner-Burton et al. 2014). This section develops an interactive theory that offers two challenges to this top-down conventional wisdom. First, the incentives of governments are not purely electoral. Ideology conditions which groups are most likely be cooperated with or repressed, interacting with electoral incentives to create a more powerful explanation of government strategy toward armed groups. Second, state control over armed groups is a variable rather than a constant. In some cases, including India’s Punjab in the 1980s, governments completely lose control of armed groups, in others, such as contemporary Libya, ruling politicians have to cooperate with powerful armed actors, and in yet others, electoral armed groups are pawns of the government. Five distinct relationships can develop between governments and electoral armed groups: groups become normalized, incorporated, purged, resilient opponents, or proxies. In two of these trajectories, the group ceases to exist (incorporation and purging); in the other three, the group continues to operate, but with varying levels of independence from and cooperation with the state (normalized, proxy, and resilient opponent groups). Political Sources of Government Strategy Government assigned armed groups different political roles. Internal security apparatuses, militaries, and politicians pay careful attention to the rhetoric and behavior of armed actors, including both existing groups and new splinter cells, in order to understand if these groups pose threats or could be possible allies. Political categorization is crucial for rendering the polity legible (Foucault 1978, Scott 1998) and providing decision rules for policy. As I discuss in greater detail below, these evaluations may change over time as initial categorization are updated and new actors enter the scene. 8 Regimes use two important variables to assess an electoral armed group’s political role: its electoral usefulness and ideological fit with the regime’s political project. Ideological fit and electoral value can align but also diverge. The ideological worldviews of ruling governments make sense of political threat. Elected officials and the security personnel they control draw on their political goals and institutional preferences to perform this crucial interpretive task. Building on Brass (1974) and Boudreau (2004), I argue that regimes have different perceptions of threat and beliefs about the acceptable “rules” of political life. Governments assess whether the current and past rhetoric and behavior of a group is seen to threaten or bolster the core symbols and political support bases upon which a government rests. For instance, a regime may be deeply averse to encouraging armed mobilization along religious lines, while perfectly willing to cooperate with armed groups that mobilize linguistic cleavages (Ganguly and Brown 2003); some governments are existentially threatened by a militant Left, but others see it as a potential ally. Ideological position determines which groups a government will look to as allies and enemies. Though ideology has been overlooked in work on state repression (Davenport 2007), it is essential for explaining regime perceptions of the value of or threat posed by armed actors. Government ideological projects are rooted in the goals of ruling parties, their bureaucracies’ and security forces’ lessons from foundational historical experiences, and beliefs about which political cleavages and symbolic appeals are politically dangerous. They are reproduced within parties, militaries, and interior ministries, creating powerful continuities that are primarily disrupted by regime change or a major change in government. Political beliefs shape both the background “common sense” (Laitin 1986) and the specific rationales deployed in deliberations and debates over how to deal with armed actors. Levitsky and Way (2012) show that even governments like Mugabe’s in Zimbabwe, generally dismissed as non-ideological 9 kleptocracies, still draw on deep ideational legacies from anti-colonial struggles that provide a shared understanding of political threat and non-material sources of regime cohesion. An armed group’s political role is further shaped by whether it can deliver concrete electoral benefits to the government (Wilkinson 2004, Lacina 2013). Politicians are forced to carefully calculate their possible path to take or hold power, and so they consider whether armed groups – within ideological constraints – can provide an advantage in voting and coalition formation. The electoral value of an armed group varies by context, but includes the ability to directly deliver votes, to act as a coalition partner at the national or regional level, and/or to use plausibly “deniable” (Carey et al. 2013) violence that demobilizes the government’s electoral opponents. Governments are most likely to collude with electoral armed groups that are ideologically compatible and able to deliver electoral benefits (Acemoglu et al. 2013); nevertheless, desperation may also induce them to cooperate with incompatible groups. Governments try to shut down groups that are not electorally useful, but the preferred strategy for achieving this goal depends on ideological fit. 3 Ideological allies are targeted for incorporation, turning party militias into police, thugs into ruling party strongmen, or street fighters into cogs in state patronage networks. Ideological opponents who cannot or will not help a government win elections, by contrast, are targeted for violent elimination. These groups cannot be easily accommodated because of political incompatibilities, and it is safest to try to eliminate their capacity to harm the regime. Armed Group Autonomy 3 Armed groups can deliver other benefits, such as operating as agents of internal control or as cross-border proxies, that I do not theorize here. On cross-border dynamics, see Byman 2005. On the use of pro-state militias, see Carey et al. 2013, Staniland 2012b. 10 Government political interests drive preferred state strategy, but governments are not hegemonic. An armed group’s organizational autonomy – its ability to generate men, manpower, and internal control independent of state support – conditions the effectiveness of these state policies and can sometimes force strategic change. Electoral armed groups are not necessarily the pawns of cunning elites; they can be powerful actors that push back against regime strategies.4 Autonomous groups emerge from preexisting social and organizational networks distinct from government patronage and sponsorship (Reno 2011, Staniland 2014). Political parties, student groups, religious networks, and other potential opposition social bases - what Wolf (1999) refers to as “fields of leverage” - become the basis for armed electoral groups. This process of “social appropriation” (McAdam, Tarrow, and Tilly 2001, 44) facilitates the creation of organizational structures impermeable to state control. Autonomous groups may cooperate with the government, but are not reliant on it. In Iraq, for instance, the Kurdish armed political parties in the north have organizational roots independent of the central state; they bargain with Baghdad rather than being controlled by it. In contrast, groups that emerge with the active sponsorship and support of a government are dependent on it for resources, manpower, and influence within the political system.5 The youth groups linked to Bangladesh’s two main political parties are a classic example, being intertwined with the parties’ patronage networks and control mechanisms (Ali 2010, 254, 281). 4 For a broader discussion of politicians and communal riots in India, see Varshney and Gubler (2012) and Wilkinson (2013). 5 This echoes the distinction that Shefter (1994) draws between political parties that emerged reliant on government patronage compared to those that mobilized outside of these patronage resources. 11 Dependent groups are easier to control or eliminate than autonomous groups. Given the difficulties of sustained, violent collective action, most electoral armed groups are likely to be dependent. Groups can shift from dependence to autonomy by building new networks and acquiring new resources flows, but this requires luck and skill. Factions of the radical sectarian militia, Lashkar-e-Jhangvi (LeJ), in Pakistan provide an example. Though initially patronized by politicians and parts of the security services in the early and mid-1990s, some factions of LeJ have now linked up with other groups in Pakistan and Afghanistan, creating new alliances that have allowed them to turn against their previous sponsors (Nasr 2002, 101-108; Zahab and Roy 2004). The Pakistani security apparatus has had to politically categorize these actors as they have emerged, leading to new relationships and state strategies. The case of the LeJ also reveals, however, that the autonomous/dependent conceptualization does not apply when an armed group is deeply divided and different factions hold varying relationships with the government. In these situations, we need to study the individual factions rather than the umbrella organization: the LeJ as an overall group is difficult to categorize because of its fragmentation, but particular factions within it can be evaluated as more autonomous or dependent. Table 1 summarizes the argument. Each cell represents a different political relationship between an armed group and the government. Within each cell the group’s organizational autonomy/dependence determines which specific outcome is most likely. Regimes may control dependent groups as armed proxies, incorporate them into the state itself, or efficiently purge these groups. Government strategy determines the trajectories of dependent groups. Organizationally autonomous groups, however, can use their power to push back against state 12 policies. Those that are ideologically compatible with or electorally useful to a government become “normalized” as mainstream political players mixing ballots and bullets; governments will either try to control them but fail, or recognize their autonomy and treat them as a business partner. Autonomous groups that are ideologically incompatible and electorally unhelpful will be targeted for suppression, but they can fight back and become resilient opponents of the government. At the end of this section I identify important mechanisms driving changes in group relationship with a government across and within the calls of Table 1. Table 1. Electoral Armed Group Trajectories (AG = Armed Group) Electorally Useful? Ideologically Yes Compatible? No Yes AG Autonomous: Normalized AG Dependent: Proxy (Deep Cooperation) [A] AG Autonomous: Normalized AG Dependent: Proxy (Thin Cooperation) [C] No AG Autonomous: Normalized AG Dependent: Incorporated [B] AG Autonomous: Resilient Opponent AG Dependent: Purged [D] Unitary and Divided Governments This discussion above assumed a unitary government that is able to engage in coherent strategies. This assumption does not always hold. In situations where there are multiple groups of elected politicians who control different security forces, we can disaggregate “the government” using my framework. For instance, in federal systems local police are often controlled by statelevel elected politicians, while the military and central security forces are controlled by national politicians. When national and state political leaders have different electoral interests or ideological goals, we should see distinct patterns of strategy toward electoral armed groups by each set of security forces. Similar fractures can develop within factionalized state apparatuses. 13 In Northeast India, for instance, local politicians and police have sometimes been accused of colluding with insurgent groups during electoral campaigns (cells A or C depending on the case) even as security forces controlled by central politicians try to destroy the same groups (cell D) (Bhaumik 2009). In southern Thailand during the Thaksin administration, the army and police were linked to different civilian factions polarized around the political power of the monarchy and traditional Bangkok elite (McCargo 2006, 9-10). Different parts of the state may act at crosspurposes because of the conflicting interests of political leaders, for the reasons that my theory highlights. Different parts of the governing apparatus will assign different groups to different roles in Table 1 and deal with them accordingly. The interactive theory is much less helpful when security forces are not beholden to elected officials, even if elections are ongoing. Politically powerful militaries, in particular, may pursue their own political and organizational interests. In these contexts, my approach should nevertheless explain the preferences and advocated policies of elected politicians, whether or not their preferred policy is implemented. This creates a further observable implication of the argument: if we see politicians disagreeing with security forces along the lines I predict (and data on these policy positions is credible), it makes us more confident that the underlying political logic I propose is operating among elected officials. With these caveats in mind, the rest of this section unpacks each trajectory, and then considers shifts between them over time. Ideologically Compatible and Electoral Useful Armed Groups [A] Electorally useful dependent groups become proxies. If their ideological outlook aligns with that of the government, it will use them as tools of the regime. These are relationships of de facto control by the government, even if it denies responsibility for the group’s behavior. Proxies in this context are often linked to the ruling party or leaders’ networks but officially distinct from 14 the state, including youth and student wings, party militias, criminals linked to the ruling regime, and provocateurs. They are unleashed against opposition politicians, their supporters, and dissidents around election time, but can be kept in reserve after an individual election has passed. This trajectory helps regimes evade international monitoring, and is likely to substantially degrade the quality of electoral representation and state accountability. Proxies have attracted the most attention in work on electoral violence, generally as the instigators of riots, intimidation, and local street clashes; they are the stereotypical lumpenproletariat shock troops of a regime deployed to try to minimize its culpability for violence (Levitsky and Way 2010, Reno 2011). In India, Brass (1997) and Wilkinson (2004) argue that local networks of criminals and Hindu nationalist organizations are strategically deployed and restrained by politicians. The “pocket armies” of Burma’s ruling party in the 1950s operated as the local enforcers of politicians in the rural countryside (Callahan 2004). When groups switch from this proxy trajectory, it is usually to become incorporated once they are no longer electorally useful. The other trajectory an armed group can follow in this political context (cell A) is becoming normalized. Normalized groups mix “mainstream” politics with the continued threat and use of violence. They participate in elections, fund-raising, and/or contentious politics in the political system but retain coercive capacity. Unlike proxies, normalized groups are free agents with their own recruiting networks, logistical and financial operations, and command structures that governments cannot easily co-opt. Because of shared electoral and ideological interests, cooperation between normalized groups and governments in this context is close and durable, but more equal than in proxy relationships. The private armies of politicians in the Philippines are an example (Sidel 1999), as are armed local powerbrokers in Nigeria who cooperate with national 15 politicians (Reno 2011). In Iraq after the American invasion, Shiiite political parties with armed militias became normalized groups linked to governing coalitions. This trajectory can undermine the influence of the “median voter” in favor of pacts and deals between the government and electoral armed groups. Electorally Useful but Ideologically Incompatible Groups [C] Most electoral armed groups are likely to be found in cell A because strategically calculating governments will try to cooperate with electorally useful groups sharing political goals. But sometimes governments cooperate with electoral armed groups despite underlying political incompatibility (cell C). This is most likely in a weakly institutionalized electoral environment with a government desperately bidding to retain power. Proxy relationships can emerge in these contexts as governments prop up dependent, but ideologically divergent, armed actors to attack electoral rivals. Armed provocateurs and splinter groups are used against the government’s electoral opponents in a shadowy world of provocateurs, collusion with warlords, and other forms of deniable electoral violence. SubSaharan Africa after the Cold War has seen a number of cases (Collier 2009, Bates 2008, Reno 1998) in which governments patronized the enemies of their enemies. Governments and their proxies in this context are strange bedfellows only able to engage in a fragile cooperation. These relationships are likely to be linked to human rights abuses, assassination campaigns, and murky and protracted violence that undermine state accountability and the quality of democracy. Proxies of convenience will be targeted for repression by the government as soon as they stop being electorally useful (cell D). We can also see normalization when, despite differences in preferences, an autonomous group is willing to cooperate with the government as part of a coalition or in a live-and-let-live 16 collusive deal. Bargaining and mutual deterrence emerge in these contexts. Examples include the relationships between the non-Shiite parts of the Lebanese state and Hezbollah and between the Kurdish Democratic Party and the central government in Baghdad. The KDP and Hezbollah are powerful actors with deeply embedded organizational structures. Normalization in this context is a transactional, often tense relationship, but the balance of power and interests can maintain cooperation. Democratic representation may completely break down as direct armed bargaining between the state and armed groups determines policy outcomes, creating “armed consociationalism” (Gayer 2014, 207). Ideologically Compatible but Electorally Unhelpful Groups (B) Some armed groups are ideologically compatible with the government but not electorally useful (cell B). Dependent groups in this context are incorporated, usually by being absorbed into the state and/or ruling party. This is most likely to happen to groups that were previously proxies after an electoral victory and/or in the face of severe criticism of the government for their actions. Such groups are compatible with and dependent on the government, and can be accommodated into the state relatively easily. This may be simply a matter of shifting them from de facto to de jure arms of the state. Folding armed groups into the “mainstream” is a crucial mechanism through which regimes centralize control over violence. In the Philippines, Human Rights Watch (2012) reports that local political clans’ private armies are often formally rebranded as state security forces, and put on the government payroll, as a way of consolidating central power and avoiding criticism from outside observers. In the early-1970s Calcutta, Kohli shows that the Indian National Congress absorbed street fighters, criminals, and other armed actors into its party structures after previously using them as proxies 17 in the brutal battles of 1967-1972 (Kohli 1990). These elements became part of the Congress as it ruled the state of West Bengal. Autonomous groups in this context, however, continue to be normalized. The government cannot incorporate them against their wishes, and since they do not pose a deep ideological threat to the regime they can be tolerated as local power brokers or opposition parties.6 This means that the armed politics found in other political contexts endures in this one as well, characterized by opportunistic cooperation between state and armed group. Electorally Unhelpful and Ideologically Incompatible Armed Groups (D) When electoral armed groups pose a serious political threat to a government, conflict is likely (cell D). This context is rare, as regimes will usually not back groups with radically different goals, and armed groups will try to avoid a debilitating reliance on hostile governments. Yet such relationships can emerge as ruling governments and their interests change and as armed groups radicalize in response to internal competition or external repression. Two mechanisms are likely to lead to this political context. The first is when a new government comes to power with different electoral and ideological interests than its predecessor, and is faced with electoral armed groups that were sponsored by the previous government. Armed group political roles shift radically after this change in power, as does state strategy. The second mechanism occurs when a politically incompatible group has been brought into the electoral arena by a desperate or miscalculating regime (as in cell C) and then radicalizes. In both of these circumstances, attempts at bargaining and compromise are challenging because of 6 I assume that autonomous groups generally prefer to maintain independence as a means of advancing their goals and interests free of government control, but when this assumption does not hold we will see incorporation in this context. 18 problems of trust and the difficulty of assessing relative power and armed group organizational autonomy (Fearon 1995). Dependent armed groups in this context are rapidly purged. A purge often happens after a government uses a politically incompatible group as a lowest-common-denominator ally (as in cell C), and then destroys it after it has served its purpose. These proxies of convenience cannot be easily incorporated into the state structure because of their distinct political origins and goals, but destroying them is straightforward. Purges also occur when a new government targets thugs and strongmen who had been dependent on the old regime. When the Burmese military seized power in 1962, for instance, it quickly eliminated the local armies of the APFPL politicians (Callahan 2004). As with incorporation, however, successful purges assert regime power and consolidate coercive capacity within the state. Resilient opponent are groups that ideologically and electorally oppose the ruling government. They are targeted for destruction because they pose an important political threat to the government.7 Unlike purged groups, however, they have the organizational capacity to fight back and resist suppression for a sustained period of time. Civil war can be avoided if the armed group and state have some overlapping interests that provide the basis for a compromise, deescalation, and a return to normalization after a period of conflict. When radicalizing armed groups or unaccommodating states (Goodwin 2001) are involved, however, a “militarized elections” pathway to civil war onset can emerge. Electoral militarization may escape the manipulation of even powerful political leaders, leading to a massive, often unexpected, violence 7 There may be situations in which an autonomous armed group deters a crackdown despite being seen as a political threat, but these relationships are likely to be fragile. 19 exploding out of electoral militarization run amok, as in the Punjab case introduced in the beginning of this article, and in some periods of Karachi’s politics described below. Dynamics and Change in Group Trajectories These state-group trajectories are not locked in stone. Groups can move from being proxies to being normalized, or transform from normalization into resilient opposition; their political roles can shift between and within the cells in Table 1. These dynamics involve contingency, interaction, and agency, and no theory can accommodate all of the pathways of change. Nevertheless, my framework helps to analyze interaction over time by identifying the importance of ideological positioning, electoral interests, and organizational autonomy. It provides a new analytical map to structures the likely pathways of change. There are important constraints on change. If a group is successfully purged or incorporated, it ends as an actor and cannot move between political roles. Conflict between a government and a resilient opponent can forestall a return to normalization if trust breaks down and a total war of annihilation develops. Normalized groups are hard to purge or incorporate, and their endurance limits what governments can do to them. Groups with a long history of adhering to a particular ideological line may not be able to credibly change their political position, at least in the short run, and may remain deeply suspect in the eyes of governments. This means that changes are not totally fluid; certain options can be off the table for historical reasons. Within these constraints, several important mechanisms drive change. The most dramatic shifts are between the cells in Table 1, creating new political relationships between regimes and armed groups. New governments can come to power with different ideological projects and/or electoral interests. The replacement of a leftist government by a right-wing coalition or the collapse of an electoral authoritarian regime by a democratizing mass movement, for instance, 20 can cause a dramatic reassessment of enemies and allies. Major coalitional changes within governments may have similar effects. Threat perceptions and electoral needs often change with regime politics. Previous proxies can be targeted for purges and resilient opponents may become normalized as political roles change. The most dramatic shifts in trajectories should therefore occur after a major change in government and/or regime, as new rulers assesses the armed landscape and armed groups probe the rules of the game. A process of violent learning often ensues in these periods (Tajima 2014), with groups and governments trying to measure their relative power and establish ideological positions. This can trigger a temporary period of conflict followed by normalization if both sides end up finding a mutually-agreeable equilibrium, or it can lead to escalating warfare. Electoral armed groups themselves can radicalize and moderate their ideological positions, both in and outside of these transitional periods. A powerful cause of uncompromising or even radicalizing ideological positions is the existence of threat of intra-movement competition and splintering (Pearlman 2011, Krause 2013/14). Adopting a rigid stance may be necessary to avoid charges of selling out or being co-opted, heightening ideological tensions and limiting opportunities for electoral cooperation. Some ideological positions may be unacceptable to the group’s supporters. This mechanism can lead to sustained conflict and keep groups in resilient opposition with a central government. Cutting in the opposite direction, however, are causes of ideological moderation. Two in particular stand out. First, electoral armed group groups may decide to cooperate with the government after realizing that their goals are unattainable and government repression too much to bear. War-weariness can force a group to operate within the government’s rules of the game as long as that position does not fundamentally undermine the organization’s raison d’etre. This 21 change is limited by internal organizational dynamics and the political preferences of a group’s social base (Kaplan 2014), so ideological positions may be quite “sticky” over time. Second, groups can moderate their ideological position to reap the benefits of patronage, political power, and protection that becoming a proxy or normalized actor confers (Reno 2011). Ideological malleability in exchange for material benefits is especially common for groups born as dependent proxies without a preexisting political agenda. As discussed earlier, changes in organizational autonomy may occur as a result of regime strategies and armed group innovation (Weinstein 2007, Staniland 2014). Shifts in this balance of organizational power can affect state-armed group trajectories within the cells in Table 1. If groups grow more or less dependent on regimes, their options and vulnerabilities change. These various processes of interaction are endogenous and iterative, but I offer a structured set of theoretical processes that can be empirically assessed and compared. Elections and Violence in Karachi Research Design This section examines Karachi’s violent electoral politics to probe in greater detail where the theory succeeds and fails. The research design leverages comparisons across groups and time in Karachi to fill out the typology in Table 1, identifying both the origins of armed group political roles and groups’ reactions to consequent government policies. These comparative cases constitute a plausibility probe (Eckstein 1975) that illustrates and establishes greater confidence in the explanatory power of the typological theory (Elman 2005), while also highlighting areas for future research. Karachi has advantages and limitations as a context for assessing my theory. Multiple armed groups have been involved in Karachi’s national and provincial elections over the last 22 three decades. These groups have had different levels of organizational autonomy and dealt with governments possessing different electoral incentives and ideological goals. This structure of variation allows a careful examination of government-armed group trajectories that holds constant many broader structural features of the polity. There is some available qualitative data that allows us to process-trace specific interactions and decision-making processes, complementing the comparisons of outcomes (George and Bennett 2005; Brady and Collier 2010). There are also important limitations to this study. As shown below, the enduring political power of Pakistan’s military means that internal security is not under the straightforward control of elected officials. The complexity of Pakistan’s internal security arrangements can undermine data quality and mask responsibility for policy outcomes decision-making processes: the Army is a powerful actor that can influence the behavior of state-level police forces, as can politicians and local criminal networks. Yet this also means that if there is substantial support for my argument in Pakistan, similar dynamics are likely to operate in more “normal” electoral contexts. The power of the Army explains why the theory fails in two important instances, but also shows that that the evidence is not being cherry-picked to support the theory. As I discuss below, Pakistan suggests the need for more systematic research on when and how militaries thwart civilian politicians in electoral environments. Empirical Overview Karachi’s politics since the 1980s have been highly militarized. Political parties have created armed wings, criminal gangs are allied with political actors, and the military has both colluded with and tried to suppress key electoral armed groups in the sprawling metropolis. Elections, policy-making, and coercion are entwined: “Violence in the city is frequently used as 23 a negotiating tactic to sway provincial- or federal-level decision-making” (Yusuf 2012, 5). I compare the Muttahida Qaumi Party (MQM), its splinter the MQM-Haqiqi (MQM-H), and local student and criminal groups that have become linked to the Pakistan People’s Party (PPP). These are the main electoral non-state armed actors in Karachi; while other militant groups have a presence in the city, including the Pakistani Taliban and Lashkar-e-Jhangvi, they are not as explicitly involved in electoral competition. Table 2 summarizes the theoretical expectations and empirical outcomes in this set of comparisons. The MQM’s organizational autonomy has consistently been high, but its electoral value and ideological compatibility with elected governments have varied over time. The MQM has been normalized when it is electorally valuable to national political leaders and when it has restrained itself from indiscriminate communal killing and/or hints at separatism. It was a resilient opponent against the Benazir Bhutto PPP-led government from 1993-1996 because it was not electorally useful to Bhutto and was locked in a brutal ethnic war with the PPP’s Sindhi base. However, the military’s crackdown on the group in 1992 shows that my theory loses explanatory power when coercion is not directed by politicians. Karachi also provides examples of proxies, purging, and incorporation. During the early 1990s the MQM-Haqiqi broke away from the MQM. It became a proxy for the military that fought the MQM and stood for elections, but in 2003 the MQM-H was purged by the army as part of a deal between Pervez Musharraf and the MQM. My theory correctly predicts its role as a proxy from 1992-2003, but the 2003 purge is a failure for the argument, which predicts incorporation. The military’s independent power helps to explain this failure. Incorporation occurred when the PPP has brought thugs, students, and gangs into its party organization. The PPP’s relationship with another armed group, the People’s Aman Committee (PAC), provides a 24 mix of normalization and resilient opposition, as a PPP-led provincial government ended up first cooperating and then attacking the PAC. Table 2. Electoral Armed Groups in Karachi (Bolded outcomes are those not correctly predicted by theory) Groups Ideological Fit Electoral Value Org. Predicted Autonomy Trajectories Actual Trajectories MQM Somewhat incompatible 1992-97, but largely compatible otherwise, especially after 1997 Compatible High 1988-89, 1990-93, 1997-8, 1999-present; Low 1990, 19931996 High Normalized (1988-93), Resilient Opponent (1990, 1993-96), Normalized (1997present) Normalized (1988-89, 1990-1992) Resilient Opponent (1990, 1992-1996) Normalized (1997present) Moderate, 19922003; Low 2003present High since 1980s Low Proxy (1992-2003), Incorporated (2003) Proxy (1992-2003) Purged (2003) Variable, though mostly Low Weak local groups incorporated into party; autonomous groups become normalized or resilient opponents Incorporation dominant pattern; PAC normalized and then resilient opponent MQM-H Local armed gangs/student groups Compatible The MQM as Normalized Electoral Armed Group, 1988-1992 In the 1980s, the mobilization of ethnic Mohajirs (Urdu-speaking migrants from prePartition India) transformed the MQM from a student organization into a major political party. This process was accompanied by substantial violence, while the MQM’s dominance of the Mohajir vote made it electorally valuable for governments trying to take and hold power in Islamabad and the Sindh Provincial Assembly. Crucially, the MQM emerged in the 1980s with a tight organizational structure rooted in student mobilization, dominated by leader Altaf Hussain, that was not dependent on state patronage or resources. Cohen describes the MQM as “a tightly organized political party structured along Leninist lines” (Cohen 2004, 216), Lieven argues that it was “built on its highly disciplined and ruthless student organization” (Lieven 2011, 253), Haq identifies its “strict party discipline” (Haq 1995, 997) and Inskeep observes that “MQM 25 politicians were fiercely disciplined” (Inskeep 2011, 172). This has been, and remains, an organizationally autonomous armed group that cannot be easily controlled or destroyed by Pakistan’s security forces. In the wake of 1988’s democratization, the MQM became a valuable electoral partner for both Nawaz Sharif’s Pakistan Muslim League (PML-N) and Benazir Bhutto’s Pakistan People’s Party (PPP). In 1988, the MQM linked up with the PPP to support Bhutto’s first government, which felt that it needed the MQM’s support in the Sindh Provincial Assembly to avoid a polarizing urban-rural divide and to bolster the PPP’s factionalized party structure in the province. In return, the MQM was allowed to operate with impunity in Karachi, despite deep underlying disagreements about the distribution of political power between the MQM and the PPP’s Sindhi ethnic base. The MQM was normalized as a mainstream actor (cell C in Table 1), agreeing to the Karachi Accord of 1988 with the PPP. However, this “very brittle relationship” (Haq 1995, 999) fell apart when the MQM clashed with Sindhi activists and PPP cadres. The MQM, as a free agent rather than a proxy, abandoned Benazir in late 1989. PPP-controlled security forces then tried to crack down on the MQM in the summer of 1990. It fought back and became a resilient opponent (Shah 2014, 169), but Benazir was soon removed from power. With Benazir’s government brought down, the MQM became part of the ruling coalition at both the Sindh and national levels between 1990 and 1992. The new Prime Minister, Nawaz Sharif, held back state coercion during the 1990-92 period, even as violence in Karachi continued. The MQM was electorally useful and broadly ideologically acceptable to the PML-N (cell A), since the MQM’s vicious battles with Sindhis and Pashtuns were far less threatening to the Punjabi-based party than to the PPP. Sharif was particularly beholden to the MQM because it 26 was essential to a tenuous coalition in the Sindh Provincial Assembly intended to keep the PPP out of power in the province (Abbas 1990b, 48). Neither Sharif nor Bhutto could incorporate the MQM into the state or their national parties even when cooperating with it. In this political context, the MQM’s “parallel rule was tolerated only as long as the MQM kept to the ‘rules’ and had an influential protector in [Sindh] Chief Minister Jam Sadiq” (Frotscher 2008, 217). The MQM was engaged in “armed clientelism” that made it a crucial political player mixing ballots with bullets (Gayer 2012, 78). Frotscher shows that during the MQM coalition periods of 1988-89 (with the PPP) and 1990-92 (with the PML-N) “the state had lost its monopoly of power to the MQM in these districts” and “murders or other crimes carried out in the name of the party were not investigated by the legal authorities” (Frotscher 2008, 175). Electoral value and organizational autonomy gave the MQM the clout to become a normalized armed party, as my theory predicts. The MQM as a Resilient Opponent, 1992-1996 The period from 1992-1996 saw a crackdown, first by the Army acting on its own initiative in 1992 and then by the second Benazir Bhutto government from 1993-1996. As noted above, the Pakistani state has multiple nodes of power, including above all the military. The army crackdown of 1992 is not explained by my argument, but the 1993-1996 period of Bhuttoled suppression is. In her second term, the MQM was not electorally valuable to Bhutto and both its rhetorical and physical attacks on the PPP’s ethnic support base made it a deep political threat. These changes in first military and then civilian political interests drove the MQM from normalization to resilient opposition. In 1992, the army went into Karachi as a part of Operation Clean-up because it felt that the MQM was threatening military interests, in particular due to the MQM’s kidnapping of an 27 Army major in 1991 and its penetration of the police in the province (Nawaz 2008, Staniland 2010). The unelected army had no electoral use for the MQM and its activities were seen as an affront to the military’s self-perception as the guardian of the state. Though the operation was ostensibly a sweep across Sindh, the Army primarily focused on the MQM, engaging in major operations in Karachi from mid-June 1992. My theory does not explain this 1992 crackdown: Sharif still had electoral uses for the MQM, but the army was able to operate as it wished. However, it is clear that the Sharif government was not in favor of the crackdown. Indeed, by August 1992, Herald reported that “the civilian and the military leadership was now completely at odds regarding the scope and execution of the army operation” which had been a “unilateral” decision by the Army (Bakhtiar 1992, 26). Shah’s (2014, 172) recent assessment agrees: the Army aggressively targeted the MQM “despite the government’s objections.” Gayer notes that the Army cracked down “apparently without Nawaz Sharif’s knowledge, let alone approval” (2014, 31), and Ahmed argues that “[Chief of Army Staff] Janjua and the corps commander of Karachi, Lieutenant General Naseer Akhtar, wanted to cut the MQM down to size, but Nawaz was not willing to do that as it was part of his ruling coalition at the Centre “(Ahmed 2013, 286). Though the MQM becoming a resilient opponent versus the military in 1992 is not predicted by my argument, it does explain the political preferences of the elected politicians, and suggests that this shift would not have occurred if Sharif had controlled the army. The MQM was able to absorb this repression without being purged; Jafri reports that military officers viewed the MQM as “a highly organized unit with a centralized command structure, damaged as it may be” (Jafri 1992, 30); Gayer (2014, 75) writes that Clean-up “brought the MQM to heel but did not break it.” 28 In 1991-2, the splinter group MQM-Haqiqi (the “Real” MQM, MQM-H) broke from Altaf Hussain’s MQM, as I discuss below, with military sponsorship and became a proxy used in both violence and elections against the MQM (Haq 1995). Sharif was removed as Prime Minister in 1993, and Benazir Bhutto returned to national power in Islamabad in 1993 without relying on the MQM. There was no electoral incentive for her to do business with the MQM (Gayer 2014, 211), and the brutal ethnic politics of Sindh made the MQM an ideological threat to the government’s preferred vision of Pakistani politics (cell D), as did rumors (some planted by the military) that the MQM might push for a separate province – or even an independent country – for urban Sindh. Negotiations between the PPP and the MQM over a coalition in the Sindh provincial assembly collapsed in early 1994, as “the utility of the MQM had gradually diminished to nothing, at least from the point of view of votes, and it was then that the PPP leadership stopped making overtures and became increasingly unwilling to talk” (Bakhtiar 1994, 31). Bhutto backed the Army crackdown, which finished at the end of 1994, while extending additional repression through Interior Ministry and provincial security forces through 1996. These forces also answer to the Army, but in this case were heavily directed by Naseerullah Babar (a retired major-general and Interior Minister under Bhutto) (Gayer 2014, 215). This 1993-1996 period of “open conflict” (Gayer 2014, 100) under Bhutto is far better explained by my theory than the 1992 Army operation. The MQM Returns to Normalization, 1997-Present Thousands died in this conflict, especially in 1995, but the MQM and the state did not end up in a total war. The Mohajir constituency’s distributive demands could be met within the confines of the political system, as long as secessionism was avoided and ethnic violence 29 calibrated. The MQM entered a “gray zone” (Auyero 2007) of ideological compatibility, with elements of both overlap and resistance to the military and civilian leadership’s goals and worldviews. This provided a basis for compromise that prevented a spiral into permanent conflict. As a result, “periods of calm and of intense violence chequeuered the 1990s” (Khan 2010, 45). The MQM returned to normalization when the second Sharif government came to power in 1997 (cell A). The MQM explicitly toned down its rhetoric and tried to portray itself as an allPakistan national party, while the PML was not invested in Sindhi ethnic assertion. It became a coalition partner of Nawaz Sharif’s second government in 1997 (Frotscher 2008, 255; Nawaz 2008, 454). Thereafter the “MQM systematized a form of violent government” (Gayer 2012, 83) in Karachi. Since 1997 – other than a falling-out with Sharif’s government in 1998 after the alleged MQM assassination of a prominent personality in Karachi – the MQM has been a consistent ally of ruling governments at the national and provincial levels. Yusuf argues that the level of national repression and cooperation by civilian leaders toward the MQM is driven by the group’s electoral and coalitional importance (Yusuf 2012, 7). Normalization endured under Pervez Musharraf’s electoral authoritarian regime (the first election, though rigged, under his rule came in 2002) and the 2008-2013 PPP-led democratic government. In exchange for stability and support, the “party was given a free hand to rule as it saw fit in urban Sindh” (Frotscher 2008, 264) under Musharraf (Gayer 2012, 78-9). Despite its bitter history with the MQM, once Asif Ali Zardari became president, the PPP made deals with the party (Gazdar 2011, 17) because it continued to be a badly needed partner for stabilizing Sindh. The PPP had learned the cost of attacking the MQM, and the MQM had a clearer sense of the acceptable rules of the game. The same rough equilibrium has held since Sharif returned for his third round in power after 2013, even as violence continues to stalk Karachi’s streets. Indeed, 30 “one of the fundamental features of the party is that it uses both violence and parliamentary politics to pursue and assert its interests” (Frotscher 2008, 130). The experience of 1992-1996 seems to have induced mutual learning: the MQM identified the limits of its influence, and civilian politicians and the military we made very aware of how resilient and disruptive the MQM could be. Karachi’s armed politics stabilized in the 2000s compared to the rapid shifts between cells in Table 1 that characterized the 1990s. Governments and armed groups can adjust their perceptions and behaviors over time. This was a dynamic process in which both ideological adjustment and electoral incentives played a central role. The MQM has been able to operate within the Pakistani political system to remarkable effect, contributing to the destabilization of several civilian governments (Gayer 2014, 31) and amassing enormous political power from this leverage. This trajectory is in sharp contrast to explicitly ethno-separatist armed groups, like those in Baluchistan and (early 1970s) East Pakistan, that have been perceived by political elites as fundamentally inimical to the idea of Pakistan (Cohen 2004, Fair 2014), or other groups in Karachi discussed below that lack organizational autonomy. Governments can do business with the MQM as long as it does not become explicitly separatist or uncontrollably communal, the MQM can protect itself from incorporation, control, or destruction because of its organizational structure, and it has therefore become an integral part of Karachi’s politics of “ordered disorder” (Gayer 2012). MQM-Haqiqi as Proxy and Purge Victim The MQM-H split from the MQM in 1992 around the time of the Army crackdown. The military provided it with guns and protection as it pursued counterinsurgency operations (Gayer 2012, 77-78; Haq 1995, 1001; Lieven 2011, 316). The MQM-H also stood for elections, though 31 without much success, making it an electoral armed group. I code it as moderately electorally useful, since it put up candidates in an effort to displace the MQM as the electoral representative of the Mohajirs. But it quickly lost discipline and it never won much electoral support, becoming an unambiguous proxy of the military (Bakhtiar and Jafri 1994, 32). It was dependent on the Army for survival, rather than having a well-established social or organizational base: Haq argues that the Army’s manipulation “profoundly delegitimized the Haqiqi among the majority of MQM supporters, who regarded the dissidents as traitors” (Haq 1995, 1001). In 2003, the MQM and Pervez Musharraf cut a deal that solidified their alliance and the MQM’s role as electoral power and armed enforcer in Karachi. The MQM-H posed no ideological challenge to the government, but it was no longer valuable for either winning seats or targeting the MQM, and had been in decline for years. The military removed the MQM-H from its areas of territorial control and targeted potential trouble-makers within the group (Gayer 2012, 78-9). Its leader, Afaq Ahmed, was jailed from 2004 to 2011. The Haqiqis had little organizational capacity with which to fight back when the state decided to dispense with them. The proxy period from 1992-2003 is explained by my theory, but this 2003 purge is not. The theory predicts that should the MQM-H should have been incorporated once it was no longer useful. This purge appears to have been used as a credible commitment to the MQM by the army, which had the power to pursue its own interests in Karachi. Street Fighters and Party Incorporation: PPP Competitive Arming The MQM is not the only party that deploys violence in Karachi. In addition to the growing insurgent threat of the Pakistani Taliban, the PPP has become increasingly armed in recent years. Journalistic and analytical accounts point to street fighters, gunmen, and violent student activists as key players in the PPP’s battles to defend itself and attack its enemies. As a 32 pair of journalists reported in 2011, “There is consensus among them [interviewees] that the combatants of this gang war were the proxies of leadership figures of the ruling Pakistan People's Party (PPP) and its Awami National Party (ANP) coalition partner, and their on-again, off-again ally, the Muttahida Qaumi Movement (MQM)” (Hadayat and Hussain 2011). The Human Rights Commission of Pakistan noted in 2011 that “[A]lmost everyone that the HRCP mission talked to spoke of the involvement of the main political parties in Karachi and their armed/militant wings in violence and other crimes” (HRCP 2011, 11). In 2013, over 2,700 people were killed in Karachi, many of them in battles linked to elections and political parties (Khan and Ashraf 2014). We have some evidence on PPP links to to electoral armed groups. The party is usually part of the ruling coalition at the Sindh provincial level, and often at the national level, meaning that its relationship with armed actors tends to approximate that between a government and armed group. The general pattern is one of incorporating student networks and local gangs among the Sindhi and, to a lesser extent, Baluch and Pashtun, ethnic populations. These small and fragmented local groups were incorporated into the PPP in two contexts: inter-ethnic boundary zones and university campus conflicts. They then become linked to the party and patronage networks of the PPP, which can provide political cover, resources, and an institutional home for protection and influence. Students’ associations on Karachi campuses – above all the PPP’s Peoples Students Federation (PSF) – have been centrally important as sources of violent activists to be channeled into the PPP rather than going rogue or establishing parallel institutional structures (Gayer 2014, 65, 71-72).8 8 For a detailed history by an eminent left-wing Pakistani journalist, see Paracha N.d. See also Gayer (2014). 33 These are not autonomous organizations; instead, they are conveyor belts for violent activists into the PPP and its often-ruling party apparatus. As Zahid (1989, 59) noted in 1989, this represents a broader pattern: “many of these student leaders have been supported and nurtured by mainstream political parties and groups and no student group has been without such backing or influence” (59). The PSF was particularly involved in clashes with the MQM in 1989 and 1990 (Abbas 1990a, 66). Criminal networks in ethnically tense areas have similarly provided specialists in violence. It seems that most are groups of neighborhood thugs who are easily controlled as proxies or sucked into the party structure (cells A and B). However, not all such local groups are dependent. There have been conflicts in some areas of Karachi, notably Lyari, as the PPP and the government forces it controls have ended up clashing with its former ally, the People’s Aman Committee (PAC) (Yusuf 2012, 12-13, 30). The PAC has its own Baloch organized crime networks on the ground that have allowed it to push back against PPP control and later repression. The PPP’s Sindh Home Minister, Zulfiqar Mirza, is alleged to have allied with the PAC in 2010-11 as protection against the MQM as part of a broader strategy of “using the PAC as its [the PPP’s] own military wing” (Gayer 2014, 221). However, his resignation, growing violence, and pressure from the MQM then led to armed clashes between government forces and the PAC (Khan 2012). After initially being normalized, the PAC became a resilient opponent in the face of crackdowns in Lyari in 2012-13 (Gayer 2014, 156-161). This case shows variation in the ability of the PPP and the security apparatus it controls to manage local allies: localized street thugs and dependent student groups could be absorbed or controlled, but the preexisting networks of the PAC gave it the power to resist becoming a simple PPP proxy. Limits of the Argument and Future Research 34 Electoral interests and ideological compatibility have frequently determined the political roles of armed groups in Karachi and the strategies that elected officials have pursued toward them, while these groups’ organizational power helps explain how they reacted. The evidence makes it clear that we can operationalize the theory and assess its match with empirical reality. Table 2 shows that most of the theoretical predictions are borne out in the historical record. However, the argument assumes that state strategy in electoral environments is influenced by electoral considerations. This approach fails to explain the timing of the first crackdown on the MQM in 1992 and the ultimate fate of the MQM-H. Both actions were taken by the Pakistan Army, which is far less electorally accountable than civilian governments, even when it is holding (dubious) elections. The military has pursued a number of strategies toward armed groups on its own accord (Fair 2014, Kapur and Ganguly 2012). Patterns of coercive restraint and repression by the Sharif, Bhutto, and Zardari elected governments, by contrast, are much closer to the theory’s predictions. The argument also explains the resistance of the Sharif government to the 1992 crackdown in Karachi, even though the Pakistan Army’s power prevented these preferences from being turned into actual policy. Future research should grapple with when and how elected officials are thwarted by security apparatuses in crafting policy. We particularly need to understand which political domains militaries determine to be “off limits” to politicians, helping to explain when my argument does and does not apply. In Pakistan, for instance, politicians are allowed to be involved in Karachi’s electoral violence, but their room to maneuver is far more limited when it comes to security policy on the northwest frontier or toward anti-India jihadist groups. 35 Armed Politics and Democracy Militarized elections are part of democratic practice in much of the world. This article has explored the relationships between governments and armed groups that emerge in these contexts. The ideology and electoral needs of governments determine how they try to manage electoral armed groups, and groups’ organizational power explains how these strategies play out over time. This theory politicizes state coercion and restraint, revealing the fascinating variety of political roles that armed groups can occupy, while integrating these groups’ ability to thwart or manipulate government strategies. Militarized elections are important beyond Pakistan. Violence and elections have been intertwined in Libya, Iraq, Nigeria, and Afghanistan in recent years, undermining attempts to consolidate meaningful democratization, and often complicating international intervention policies. Policymakers and analysts are likely to be unpleasantly surprised if they do not take electoral armed groups seriously: they are not simple pawns of regimes, but can instead dominate patronage networks, challenge state power, or carve out enduring local fiefdoms. Understanding the ideological and electoral roots of government policy can in turn make better sense of strategies that seem counterproductive or irrational to outside observers. These claims have broader theoretical implications. Conventional studies of political violence distinguish between civil wars, electoral violence, and state building. This article challenges these categories: militarized elections can lead to everything from state centralization to civil war to violent bargaining. Researchers should explore interactions between states and armed groups across a wide variety of related substantive areas, from counterinsurgency to regime politics. We need new ways of studying the armed politics that define a contemporary era in which elections have spread but political violence endures. 36 References Abbas, Zaffar. 1990a. “Back From the Brink?” Herald, May: 65-70. ---. 1990b. “The Sindh Card,” Herald, September: 48-54. Acemoglu, Daron, James A. Robinson, and Rafael Santos. 2013. The Monopoly of Violence: Evidence from Colombia. Journal of the European Economic Association 11 (s1): 5–44. Ahmed, Ishtiaq. 2013. The Pakistan Garrison State: Origins, Evolution, Consequences. Karachi: Oxford University Press. Ali, S. Mahmud. 2010. Understanding Bangladesh. Columbia University Press. Bakhtiar, Idrees. 1992. “Is the Army here to stay?” Herald, August: 22-26. ---. 1994. “What does the MQM really want?” Herald, May: 27-33 Bakhtiar, Idrees, and Hasan Iqbal Jafri. 1994. “Eye for an Eye,” Herald, July: 27-35. Bates, Robert H. 2008. When Things Fell Apart: State Failure in Late-Century Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press. Bekoe, Dorina Akosua Oduraa. 2012. Voting in fear: electoral violence in Sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace. Boudreau, Vincent. Resisting Dictatorship: Repression and Protest in Southeast Asia. Cambridge ; New York: Cambridge University Press, 2004. Brady, Henry E, and David Collier, eds. 2010. Rethinking Social Inquiry: Diverse Tools, Shared Standards, 2nd ed. Lanham, Md: Rowman & Littlefield. Brancati, Dawn, and Jack L. Snyder. 2011. Rushing to the Polls: The Causes of Premature Postconflict Elections. Journal of Conflict Resolution 55 (3): 469–492. Brass, Paul R. 1974. Language, Religion and Politics in North India. London: Cambridge University Press. 37 Brass, Paul R. 1997. Theft of an Idol: Text and Context in the Representation of Collective Violence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Brown, Michael and Sumit Ganguly, eds. 2003. Fighting Words: Language Policy and Ethnic Relations in Asia. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. Byman, Daniel. 2005. Deadly Connections: States That Sponsor Terrorism. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Cohen, Stephen P. 2004. The Idea of Pakistan. Washington, D.C: Brookings Institution Press. Eckstein, Harry. 1975. “Case studies and theory in political science.” In Greenstein, F., and N. Polsby, eds. Handbook of political science, vol. 7, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 79–138. Elman, Colin. 2005. “Explanatory Typologies in Qualitative Studies of International Politics.” International Organization 59 (02): 293–326. Fair, C. Christine. 2014. Fighting to the End: The Pakistan Army’s Way of War. New York: Oxford University Press. Fearon, James D. 1995. Rationalist Explanations for War. International Organization 49 (3): 379–414. Foucault, Michel. 1995. Discipline & Punish: The Birth of the Prison. New York: Vintage Books. Frotscher, Ann. 2008. Claiming Pakistan: the MQM and the fight for belonging. 1. ed. BadenBaden: Nomos. Gayer, Laurent. 2014. Karachi: Ordered Disorder and the Struggle for the City. Oxford: Oxford University Press. ---. 2012. “Political Turmoil in Karachi.” Economic and Political Weekly 47(31): 76–84. Gazdar, Haris. 2011. “Karachi’s Violence: Duality and Negotiation.” SPO Discussion Paper 38 Series, No 10. George, Alexander L., and Andrew Bennett. Case Studies and Theory Development in the Social Sciences. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2005. Hadayat, Amjad and Tom Hussain. 2011. Political violence shifts to Karachi. The National, November 11 < http://www.thenational.ae/news/world/south-asia/political-violence-shiftsto-karachi#full>. Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., Susan D. Hyde, and Ryan S. Jablonski. 2014. When Do Governments Resort to Election Violence? British Journal of Political Science 44 (01): 149–179. Haq, Farhat. 1995. “Rise of the MQM in Pakistan: Politics of Ethnic Mobilization.” Asian Survey 35(11): 990–1004. Hyde, Susan D., and Nikolay Marinov. 2012. Which Elections Can Be Lost? Political Analysis 20 (2): 191–210. Human Rights Commission of Pakistan (HRCP). 2011. "Karachi: Unholy Alliances for Mayhem.” Lahore: Human Rights Commission of Pakistan. Human Rights Watch. 2012. “Philippines: Keep Promise to Disband Paramilitaries.” http://www.hrw.org/news/2012/03/30/philippines-keep-promise-disband-paramilitaries. Hyde, Susan D. 2011. The Pseudo-Democrat’s Dilemma: Why Election Monitoring Became an International Norm. Cornell University Press. Hyde, Susan D., and Nikolay Marinov. 2012. Which Elections Can Be Lost? Political Analysis 20 (2): 191–210. Jafri, Hasan. 1990. “MQM: A Fight to the Finish?” Herald, July: 25-30. Kaplan, Morgan. 2014. “How Civilian Perceptions Affect Patterns of Violence and Competition in Multi-Party Insurgencies.” Working paper, University of Chicago. 39 Kapur, S. Paul, and Sumit Ganguly. 2012. The Jihad Paradox: Pakistan and Islamist Militancy in South Asia. International Security 37 (1): 111–141. Khan, Faraz. “Violence 101: A primer to the Lyari gang war.” Express Tribune, May 2. http://tribune.com.pk/story/372834/violence-101-a-primer-to-the-lyari-gang-war-karachi/ Khan, Faraz and Gibran Ashraf. 2014. “Karachi 2013: the Deadliest Year of all.” Express Tribune, January 6. Khan, Nichola. 2010. Mohajir militancy in Pakistan: violence and transformation in the Karachi conflict. London ; New York: Routledge. Kohli, Atul. 1990. Democracy and discontent: India’s growing crisis of governability. Cambridge University Press. Krause, Peter. “The Structure of Success: How the Internal Distribution of Power Drives Armed Group Behavior and National Movement Effectiveness.” International Security 38, no. 3 (2013/2014): 72–116. Lacina, Bethany. 2013. How Governments Shape the Risk of Civil Violence: India’s Federal Reorganization, 1950–56. American Journal of Political Science. doi: 10.1111/ajps.12074. Laitin, David. 1986. Hegemony and culture : politics and religious change among the Yoruba. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan A. Way. 2010. Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes After the Cold War. Cambridge University Press. ---. 2012. “Beyond Patronage: Violent Struggle, Ruling Party Cohesion, and Authoritarian Durability.” Perspectives on Politics 10 (4): 869–89. Lieven, Anatol. 2011. Pakistan: A Hard Country. 1st ed. New York: PublicAffairs. 40 McAdam, Doug, Sidney Tarrow, and Charles Tilly. 2001. Dynamics of Contention. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Nasr, S.V.R. 2002. Islam, the State and the Rise of Sectarian Militancy in Pakistan. In Pakistan: Nationalism Without a Nation?, ed. Christophe Jaffrelot, 85–114. New Delhi: Manohar. Nawaz, Shuja. 2008. Crossed swords: Pakistan, its army, and the wars within. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Flores, Thomas Edward, and Irfan Nooruddin. 2012. The Effect of Elections on Postconflict Peace and Reconstruction. The Journal of Politics 74 (02): 558–570. Paracha, Nadeem F. N.d. Student politics in Pakistan: A celebration, lament, and history. <http://nadeemfparacha.wordpress.com/student-politics-in-pakistan-a-celebration-lamenthistory/>. Paris, Roland. 2004. At War’s End: Building Peace After Civil Conflict. Cambridge, U.K: Cambridge University Press. Pearlman, Wendy. 2011. Violence, Nonviolence, and the Palestinian National Movement. 1st ed. Cambridge University Press. Radin, Andrew. 2012. “The Limits of State-Building: The Politics of War and the Ideology of Peace.” Ph.D dissertation, MIT. Reno, William. 2011. Warfare in independent Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press. Roessler, Philip G. 2005. “Donor-Induced Democratization and the Privatization of State Violence in Kenya and Rwanda.” Comparative Politics 37(2): 207–227. Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing like a state: how certain schemes to improve the human condition have failed. New Haven, CT: London: Yale University Press. 41 Shah, Aqil. 2014. The Army and Democracy: Military Politics in Pakistan. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Sidel, John. 1999. Capital, coercion, and crime: bossism in the Philippines. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Snyder, Jack L. 2000. From voting to violence: democratization and nationalist conflict. New York: Norton. Staniland, Paul. 2010. Cities on Fire: Social Mobilization, State Policy, and Urban Insurgency. Comparative Political Studies 43 (12): 1623 –1649. Staniland, Paul. 2012. States, Insurgents, and Wartime Political Orders. Perspectives on Politics 10 (02): 243–264. Staniland, Paul. 2014. Networks of Rebellion: Explaining Insurgent Cohesion and Collapse. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Straus, Scott, and Charlie Taylor. 2012. Democratization and Electoral Violence in Sub-Saharan Africa, 1990-2008. In Voting in fear: electoral violence in Sub-Saharan Africa, edited by Dorina Akosua Oduraa Bekoe, 15–38. Washington, D.C.: United States Institute of Peace. Varshney, Ashutosh. 2002. Ethnic Conflict and Civic Life: Hindus and Muslims in India. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Varshney, Ashutosh, and Joshua R. Gubler. 2012. “Does the State Promote Communal Violence for Electoral Reasons?” India Review 11 (3): 191–199. Von Borzyskowski, Inken. 2014. A Double Edged Sword: International Influences on Election Violence. PhD dissertation, University of Wisconsin-Madison. Wilkinson, Steven. 2004. Votes and Violence: Electoral Competition and Ethnic Riots in India. Cambridge, U.K: Cambridge University Press. 42 ---. 2013. “Electoral Competition, the State, and Communal Violence: A Reply.” India Review 12 (2): 92–107. Wolf, Eric R. 1999 [1969]. Peasant Wars of the Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press. Wood, Elisabeth Jean. 2000. Forging Democracy from Below: Insurgent Transitions in South Africa and El Salvador. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Yusuf, Huma. 2012. Conflict Dynamics in Karachi. Peaceworks No. 82. Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace. http://www.usip.org/sites/default/files/PW82Conflict%20Dynamics%20in%20Karachi.pdf Zahab, Mariam Abou, and Olivier Roy. 2004. Islamist Networks: The Afghan-Pakistan Connection. Columbia University Press. Zahid, Shahid. 1989. “Licence to Kill?” Herald, August, 57-59.
© Copyright 2024 ExpyDoc