International Banking and Financial Stability in the Euro Area: Do We Really Need a Federal Institution? Gauthier Vermandel This version: April 8, 2014 (Preliminary draft) Abstract What should be the role of the federal level in the settlement of macroprudential measures? This paper evaluates the consequences of a symmetric treatment of countries regarding the implementation of macroprudential measures in the Eurozone. In an estimated two-country DSGE model accounting for alternative macroprudential instruments and implementations schemes, we get four main results. First, macroprudential measures lead to an highest increase in welfare at the union level if they take into account national features. Second, macroprudential policy implementation leads to winners (the peripheral countries) and losers (the core countries). Third, using a Nash bargaining game, we …nd that national-adjusted macroprudential measures need a federal institution to impose coordination between EU members, as countries have incentives to choose the second best non cooperative outcome. Fourth, cross-border loan ‡ows are a critical feature to address cooperation incentives issues, we observe a Nash equilibrium reversal in banking autarky. JEL classi…cation: E32; E44; E52; F36; F41; Keywords: Banking Globalization, Monetary and Macroprudential policy, Banking Union, Euro Area, Financial Accelerator, DSGE Two-Country Model, Bayesian Estimation CREM, UMR CNRS 6211, Université de Rennes I, Rennes, [email protected] Prepared for the XI Macro…. 1 France. E-mail: This paper analyses how national and federal concerns should be balanced in designing the macroprudential mandate1 in a monetary union such as the Eurozone. As recommended by the IMF (IMF, 2013), the legislation regarding national macroprudential systems should include adequate provisions regarding the objective, the functions and the powers of the macroprudential authority. Namely, clear objectives (with explicit targets) should guide the decision-making process and enhance the accountability of authorities. The key macroprudential functions should include the identi…cation of systemic risks, the formulation of the appropriate policy response and the implementation of the policy response through adequate rulemaking. Finally, the macroprudential authority should be empowered to issue regulations, collect information, supervise regulated entities and enforce compliance with applicable rules. The institutional organization of macroprudential policy is original in the Eurozone, as it is the only supranational setup yet to be observed2 . As they constitute an integrated …nancial area, European countries have taken into account the fact that …nancial stability should be treated as a public good and that isolated national actions may undermine the conduct of an appropriate macroprudential policy. A range of new institutions have been established following the report of De Larosière (2009). The European Financial Stability Framework accounts for a macroprudential considerations through the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB). This institution is intended to encourage appropriate macroprudential actions by the national regulators to overcome or mitigate systemic risk. The role of this institution is still under de…nition, as the recent evolution towards the banking union reinforces the role of the ECB in the supervision of this policy. Furthermore, more symmetric practices between union members are encouraged. One of the aspects of the recent institutional evolution regarding the role of macroprudential is to consider the degree of symmetry that should be imposed in coordinated decisions. This question arises since the other two main macroeconomic policy tools are applied symmetrically to Eurozone members: monetary policy reacts to union wide aggregates while the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP) imposes common rules on national debts and de…cits. The aim of this paper is to evaluate the consequences of imposing symmetric 1 Broadly de…ned, the …nal objective of macroprudential policy is to prevent or mitigate systemic risks that arise from developments within the …nancial system, taking into account macroeconomic developments, so as to avoid periods of widespread distress. The main threat of this policy is to assess and control risk at the aggregate level, in contrast to microprudential measures that concentrate on individual actors. 2 For a synthetic presentation of the various institutional situations observed in real life practices regarding the de…nition of the macroprudential mandate, see (Nier et al., 2011). In some cases, it involves a reconsideration of the institutional boundaries between central banks and …nancial regulatory agencies (or the creation of dedicated policymaking committees), while in other cases, e¤orts are made to favor the cooperation of authorities within the existing institutional structure. (Nier et al., 2011) …nd that the vast majority of arrangements that are in place or are being developed across countries can be organized in seven models, which in turn form three broad groups of models that di¤er in the degree of institutional integration between central bank and regulatory agencies. 2 practices in a macroprudential mandate that is already based on the cooperation between agents. We develop a two-country DSGE model that accounts for some major features of the Eurozone regarding the problem at hands (key role of the banking system, cross-border bank loans, heterogeneity credit and business cycles) to provide a quantitative evaluation of welfare gains coming from a more symmetric treatment of countries in the implementation of macroprudential measures. In this model, heterogeneity between the member countries of the Eurozone is accounted for by distinguishing core countries and peripheral countries3 . We introduce two major novelties in the analysis. First, regarding the choice of macroprudential measures, we assume that, according to Blanchard et al. (2013) classi…cation, the macroprudential authorities can use two instruments: to a¤ect the lending conditions, they react to the level of bank capital requirement, while, on the borrowing side, they react to the evolution of the loan to income ratio. These macroprudential concerns a¤ect in a countercyclical way the loan interest rates faced by entrepreneurs to …nance investment. Second, we contrast three possibilities regarding the implementation of macroprudential decisions: (i) a coordinated de…nition of macroprudential measures based on the choice of optimal national policy parameters; (ii) a coordinated de…nition of macroprudential measures based on the choice of optimal national policy parameters for borrowing conditions and an homogenous value for the parameter related to bank capital requirements; (iii) an homogenous de…nition of all macroprudential measures. The model is estimated with Bayesian methods on Eurozone quarterly data over the sample period 1999Q1 to 2013Q24 . The interest of DSGE models to deal with this problem is that they provide an toolkit for deriving the optimal value of the macroprudential stance and for performing welfare analysis to rank the alternative macroprudential coordination schemes. We report the welfare ranking of alternative macroprudential policy schemes in terms of an increase in permanent consumption for the Eurozone, core countries and peripheral countries. Our main results can be stated as follows : First, macroprudential measures increase welfare at the union level from 0.690% to 0.886% of permanent consumption. The ranking clearly shows that a country-adjusted macroprudential mandate o¤ers the best performance in terms of unconditional consumption. However, this situation leads to winners (the peripheral countries) and losers (the core countries). Second, we …nd that imposing a common rule on capital requirements between countries mitigates the welfare loss for the Core area. Third, using a simple Nash bargaining game, we …nd that without a federal institution that obliges the euro members to coordonate macroprudential policies, the rational strategy for national governments is to choose the non cooperative outcome. These incentives 3 The criterion to divide the Eurozone in two blocks is discussed in the following section. Core countries: Austria, Belgium, Germany, Finland, France, Luxembourg and Netherlands. Peripheral countries: Spain, Greece, Ireland, Italy and Portugal. 4 To our knowledge, the design of macroprudential measures has been approached by Pariès et al. (2011), Quint and Rabanal (2013), Kannan et al. (2009), Benes and Kumhof (2011), Pariès et al. (2011), Angelini et al. (2012), Bailliu et al. (2012), Beau et al. (2012), Collard et al. (2012), Rubio and Carrasco-Gallego (2012), Angeloni and Faia (2013), Brzoza-Brzezina et al. (2013), Lambertini et al. (2013), Medina and Roldós (2013), Suh (2014) and Kincaid and Watson (2013). 3 not to cooperate brings rationally the monetary union in a second best situation. Fourth, cross-border loan ‡ows are a critical feature to address incentives issues, we observe a nash equilibrium reversal in banking autarky. The paper is organized as follows: section 1 describes the institutional background and some stylized facts regarding the situation of the Eurozone, section 2 outlines the model and the de…nition of macroprudential policies, section 3 presents the results and section 4 concludes. 1 The institutional Background Following the report of De Larosière (2009), several new institutions have been created at the EU level since January 2011 under the European System of Financial Supervision (ESFS) to ensure supervision of the Union’s …nancial system. Among these agencies, the European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) is responsible for the macroprudential oversight of the …nancial system within the European Union. The role of this independent agency is based on soft power, as it is aimed at coordinating prudential decisions for countries participating to the Eurozone and other European countries. It is intended to issue risk warnings and encourage appropriate national macroprudential actions to overcome or mitigate systemic risk. The ECB provides analytical, statistical, logistical and administrative support to the ESRB whose powers are purely advisory, including the authority to make its advice public. As shown in Figure 1, di¤erent policy initiatives have been taken since the creation of the ESRB, and a road map has been set to enhance more homogenous practices among countries participating to this structure. This calendar can be analyzed as providing a smooth transition towards a more centralized and symmetric system. In particular, the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM) initiative may modify the original organization of macroprudential implementation for countries participating to this structure. As noted by ESRB (2013, report October), it should be necessary to rediscuss the distribution of responsibility between the European Central Bank and the National Central Agencies in the conduct of macro-prudential policy to move towards a more centralized model: as the ECB will be in charge of the micro-prudential instruments which will be used for macroprudential purposes it should also be in charge of macro-prudential policy. The main task of the NCAs would be to provide information about their national business/housing cycles conditions and to make recommendations to the ECB, which would take the …nal decision. The move towards more symmetric practices in the conduct of macroprudential practices can be justi…ed on an economic ground as countries belonging to the Eurozone form an integrated …nancial area. In this area, banks provide the main liquidity to the system and cross-border banking has reached a value representing 24% of Eurozone GDP before the …nancial crisis of 2008. The transfer of macroprudential powers to the Federal level can thus make sense as cross-border banking activities have increased the interconnection of …nancial decisions in the Eurozone. 4 The calendar December 2011 : The ESRB recommends Member States to establish a legal mandate for national macro-prudential authorities by June 2013. December 2012 : The Council agreed on a regulation creating a single supervisory mechanism (SSM) which will be responsible for the micro and macro-prudential supervision of all banks in the participating countries with the ECB acting as European supervisor ”responsible for the effective and consistent functioning” of the mechanism. April 2013 : The ESRB recommends Member States to ensure a minimum set of instruments is available, and identifies a common benchmark for intermediate objectives and instruments. January 2014 : The new regulatory framework for banks enters into force (CRD4/CRR). Summer 2014 : The SSM acquires some macro-prudential powers for instruments included in the CRD4/CRR, namely those related to banks. December 2014 : Deadline ESRB recommendation on intermediate objectives and instruments. December 2015 : Deadline ESRB recommendation on strategy. Figure 1: Road map of the newly created institutions in the European Union Setting homogenous macroprudential rules at the union level can be considered as a solution to a problem of externalities. Externalities arise from the fact that national authorities do not internalize their contribution to federal …nancial instability. Two macroprudential functions outlined by the IMF legal de…nition are concerned. First, regarding the identi…cation of systemic risks, where …nancial institutions have a¢ liates in multiple jurisdictions, this complicates the assessment of systemic risk and can lead to con‡icts between home and host authorities. According to the home country principle, national authorities are only able to assess the …nancial disequilibrium of their national intermediaries. Secondly, the formulation of the appropriate policy response should be made at the federal level, as cross-border spillovers cannot be ignored. Indeed, lack of forceful macroprudential action in one country can increase the likelihood of crises, imposing negative externalities on other countries. Furthermore, national policies to contain risks from a rapid build-up of domestic credit can lead to an increase in the provision of cross-border credit. Finally, policies to strengthen the resilience of systemic institutions in one country can cause their activities to migrate to other countries. However, the choice of homogenous values for the macroprudential instruments may a¤ect the implementation of the appropriate policy response. To be e¤ective these policies should also be tailored to the situation of economies. The problem 5 500 450 (a) Corporate Credit per capita millions euro (b) Corporate Credit Spread Credit minus refi rate (c) Current Account % of GDP 4% 0% 400 350 300 3% 2% 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 −5 % 2005 2010 Core countries 2000 2005 2010 Peripheral countries Figure 2: Regional divergences in the UEM is that national situations regarding …nancial disequilibrium are heterogeneous. In Figure 2.c), we separate the Eurozone in two groups according to their status in terms of surplus or de…cit of their current account. As noticed, situations are di¤erent. A descriptive exercise regarding the attribution to the ECB of a simple rule that reacts to the growth rate of loans clearly shows the problem associated to the conduct of an homogenous decision at the federal level. The fact that …nancial cycles are mainly national may overcome the gain to conduct symmetric macroprudential policies, as it should be optimal to target in a speci…c way national development in a tailored way that may di¤er from countries to countries. More particularly, the recent …nancial turmoil highlights very important di¤erences in the credit cycles. Particularly, Figure 2.b) shows that the transmission of monetary policy via the credit channel remains di¢ cult as the wedge between the corporate credit rate and the re…nancing rate is still widening in periphery. According to Figure 2.a) and Figure 2.b), Periphery may require a di¤erent implementation of macroprudential policy as peripheral countries experienced an explosive growth of credit followed by a sharp drop as well as a rise of the corporate bond yield. Thus, the main question that arises from this short description of the main stylized fact is to evaluate wether an institutional evolution leading to more symmetric practices could be an e¢ cient solution to conduct macroprudential measures in the Eurozone. 2 The Analytical Framework This section introduces a two-country DSGE model that accounts for the main speci…cities of the Eurozone for the question at hands (namely …nancial heterogeneities and cross-border loans). In this setting, macroprudential policies are implemented using two instruments that are set cooperatively between union members. 6 2.1 A Description of the model Our model5 describes a monetary union made of two asymmetric areas i 2 fh; f g (where h is for home and f for foreign parts) of relative sizes n and 1 n. As shown in Figure 3, each part of the monetary union is populated by consumers, intermediate and …nal producers, entrepreneurs, capital suppliers and a banking system. Regarding the conduct of macroeconomic policy, we assume national …scal authorities and a common central bank. We present the model anticipating the symmetric equilibrium across households, …rms and banks that populate the economy. d Deposits Dh,t Bank Central Bank Refinancing Rate Rt Bank Lsh,t Production Ch,t Cross-Borders Loans Investment Flows Consumption Flows Lsf,t Production Cf,t Household Household d Deposits Df,t Figure 3: The model of a two-country monetary union with international bank loan ‡ows d Households The representative household supplies Hi;t hours of work, saves Di;t P1 e"i;t+ U (Ci;t+ ; Hi;t+ ), where and maximizes utility intertemporally Et =0 Ci;t is the consumption, 2 (0; 1) is the subjective discount factor and "i;t is an exogenous shock to preferences. The period utility function takes the form 1+ L 1 c c i 0 is the curvature = 1 + Li where Li U (Ci;t ; Hi;t ) Ci;t i = (1 i Hi;t i) c coe¢ cient in the disutility of labor and i 0 is the risk aversion coe¢ cient. The consumption basket of the representative household is composed of home and for( 1)= ( 1)= C 1= 1= C eign goods Ci;t = ((1 Chi;t +( C Cf i;t ) =( 1) where 1 i ) i ) i > 1=2 is the home bias in consumption and 0 is the elasticity of substitution between home and foreign goods. Firms There is a continuum of monopolistically competitive …rms, each producing di¤erentiated goods using hours of work and capital inputs Ki;t and set production prices Pi;t according to the Calvo model. Output supplied by …rms is A 1 Yi;t = e"i;t Ki;t Hi;t where "A 2 [0; 1] i;t is an innovation to the productivity and 5 The whole model is presented in appendix. 7 is the share of capital services in the production. According to the Calvo mechanism, each period …rms are not allowed to reoptimize the selling price with probability pi but price increases of pi 2 [0; 1] at last period’s rate of price in‡ation, p Pi;t = i;ti 1 Pi;t 1 where i;t = Pi;t =Pi;t 1 . Under this setting, it is possible to derive the aggregate in‡ation rate of production goods, it is de…ned by the function, i;t = f (Et i;t+1 ; i;t 1 ; mci;t ) where mci;t is the marginal cost of production. Entrepreneurs We add a borrowing constraint to the production sector to implement a banking sector in the model. We standardly introduce an entrepreneurial sector that buys capital at price Qt in t and uses that capital in the production in period t + 1. Under this assumption, the capital arbitrage equak = tion implies that the expected rate of return on capital is given by 1 + Ri;t+1 Et [Zi;t+1 + (1 ) Qi;t+1 ] =Qi;t where 2 [0; 1] and and Zi;t are respectively the depreciation rate and the marginal product of capital. Assuming that entrepreneurs are credit-constrained, they …nance capital by their net wealth Ni;t k and lending LH i;t+1 subject to external habits hi 2 [0; 1]. The balance sheet of the entrepreneur then writes, Qi;t Ki;t+1 = LH i;t+1 + Ni;t+1 . The entrepreneur has access to domestic and foreign banks to meet its balance sheet, Li;t+1 = ( 1)= ( 1)= L 1= ((1 Lhi;t+1 + ( Li )1= Lf i;t+1 ) =( 1) where Li represents the percentage i ) L , is of cross-border loan ‡ows in the monetary union. The total cost of loans, Pi;t L L L 1 L L 1 1=(1 ) L thus de…ned according to, Pi;t = ((1 + i (Rf;t ) ) where Ri;t i )(Rh;t ) denotes the credit rate set by bank in country i. The representative entrepreneur conducts a mass ! 2 [! min ; +1) of heterogenous investment projects drawn from Pareto distribution. The rentability of the k ! th investment project is, ! 1 + Ri;t+1 . There is a critical project ! ci;t that determines the threshold of pro…tability of the …rm. Aggregating projects above the threshold, we can compute the share of pro…table projects i;t in the economy i. Supposing that entrepreneurs are pessimistic as De Grauwe (2010) regarding their expected aggregated return ! on investment projects, we …nd the …nancial acceleration equation as in Bernanke et al. (1999). The external …nance premium drives a wedge between the expected return on capital and the expected return demanded k L by banks and takes the form, Ri;t =Pi;t = {i f (Qi;t Ki;t+1 =Ni;t+1 (e)) where {i > 0 measures the elasticity of the premium with respect to leverage. Banks The representative banks collects monopolistically deposits Di;t from households, borrows funds LRF i;t from the central bank and monopolistically pros vide loans Li;t to entrepreneurs. The balance sheet writes, Lsi;t+1 = Di;t+1 +LRF i;t+1 + BKi;t+1 . Following Pariès et al. (2011), we measure the pass-through of interest rates by supposing that the representative bank sets the deposit and credit rates in staggered basis à la Calvo. Letting Li ( D i ) denotes the country speci…c probability of the bank not being able to reset it credit (deposit) interest rate. The aggregate D D D deposit rate writes, Ri;t = f Et Ri;t+1 ; Rt ; "D i;t where "i;t is a markup shock and Rt is the (taylored) ECB re…nancing rate. The New Keynesian Phillips Curve for deposit rates implies that the expected future rate depends on the re…nancing rate markup and exogenous shock. Similarly, the aggregate credit rate is de…ned by, 8 L L L Ri;t = f Et Ri;t+1 ; Et i;t+1 ; Rt . Solving forward Ri;t , one can see that current and expected future ECB rate Rt and …rms pro…tability Et i;t+1 drive today’s credit rates. Capital Suppliers The representative capital producer buys deprecated capital stock (1 ) Ki;t and investment goods Ii;t and produces new capital goods Ki;t+1 at a price Qi;t . Capital supplier buys home and foreign investment goods, Ii;t = 1= ( 1)= ( 1)= I 1= I Ihi;t If i;t ( 1 + Ii ) =( 1) where 1 i i > 0:5 is the home bias in its consumption basket. Monetary Policy Finally, monetary authorities choose the nominal interest rate according to a standard Taylor rule Rt = f cu;t ; Yu;t ; "R where cu;t and t Yu;t are the growth rates of price and GDP of the monetary union and "R t is an exogenous monetary policy shock. 2.2 Macroprudential Policy In this paper, we take into account the classi…cation initially introduced by Blanchard et al. (2013). We assume that macroprudential policy is implemented through two instruments: one directed toward the …nancial stability of the lender, the other towards the borrower. First regarding lenders, we assume that macroprudential policy account for a ratio related to the Basel I-like capital requirement of the banking system (Pariès et al., 2011) BKi;t+1 KRBi;t = f ; (1) Lsi;t+1 where KRBi;t implies that the bank must pay a quadratic cost whenever the capital-to-assets ratio BKi;t+1 =Lsi;t+1 moves away from a calibrated optimal target6 . Second, regarding borrowers, we assume that macroprudential policy accounts for the evolution of the loan-to-income ratio (Gelain et al., 2012), LT Ii;t = Ldi;t+1 Yi;t Ldi : Yi (2) where Ldi;t+1 denotes the lending demand from the home private sector and Yi;t is the output. Thus when LT Ii;t increases, it is interpreted by macroprudential authorities as an excessive growth to credit in comparison to activity. As noticed, in these two expressions ((1)) and ((2)), the value of loans that is taken into account di¤ers in the two instruments, given the possibility of national banks to engage in cross border lending. Thus, the instrument directed toward 6 Following Gerali et al. (2010) and (Pariès et al., 2011), the quadratic cost added in the bank 2 1 B s maximization program writes, ACi;t BKi;t+1 =Lsi;t+1 BKi;t+1 . After maxi2 BKi =Li L mizing, the marginal cost of loans takes the form, M Ci;t = f Et i;t+1 ; Rt + i KRBi;t where B KRBi;t = @ACi;t =@Lsi;t+1 = BKi =Lsi BKi;t+1 =Lsi;t+1 9 BKi;t+1 =Lsi;t+1 2 the lending side of the economy accounts for the supply of loans in the country, while the instrument directed towards the borrowing side accounts for the fact that national agents can borrow from di¤erent national sources. However, neglecting the possibility for banks to engage in cross-border activities would make both instruments substitutable in the evaluation of systemic risk at the national level. As in Quint and Rabanal (2013), macroprudential instruments a¤ect the general equilibrium of the model through the lending conditions of commercial banks. A tightening of credit conditions due to macroprudential measures will thus increase the interest rate faced by borrowers. In the presence of macroprudential regulations, the marginal cost of loans mcLi;t faced by borrowers is altered by KRBi;t and LT Ii;t at a degree i and 'i respectively, mcLi;t = f Et i;t+1 ; Rt + i KRBi;t (3) + 'i LT Ii;t : The marginal cost is the main determinant of the credit rate in the economy7 . As shown in Table 1, our analysis of the optimal level of coordination of macroprudential policies contrasts three situations: in the …rst situation (a), we allow countries to set optimally all parameters, in the second situation (b), we impose a symmetric value on bank capital ratios in the monetary union and in the third situation (c), we impose symmetry on all parameters of the macroprudential scheme. All parameters are set to maximize the joint welfare of union participants. The details of the scenarios are set in Table 1. Scheme Instrument a ) Total National b ) Partial Symmetric c ) Total Symmetric KRB h;t = 6 KRB f;t ; LT I h;t = 6 LT I f;t KRB h;t = 6 KRB f;t ; LT I h;t = 6 LT I f;t KRB h;t = 6 KRB f;t ; LT I h;t = 6 LT I f;t Penalization h h h 6= = = f f f ; 'h = 6 'f ; 'h = 6 'f ; 'h = ' f Table 1: Di¤erent Implementation Scenarios of Macroprudential Policy 3 The Suboptimality of Homogenous Macroprudential Decisions This section summarizes the results of the analysis. These results are obtained given the estimation of the model presented in appendix B. We present some clear evidence of the sub optimality of macroprudential decisions aimed at imposing homogenous practices to all countries participating to the Eurozone. We then turn to the discussion of the enforceability of the optimal cooperative situation using a Nash bargaining game. 7 As described in section 2, the new keynesian Phillips curve for credit rates implies that the L L L credit rates are determined by Ri;t = f Et Ri;t+1 ; mcL i;t where mci;t is the marginal cost of loans. 10 3.1 Winners and losers of di¤erent policy regimes in the EMU The results are reported in Table 2. The …rst part of this table evaluates the welfare gains - in terms of permanent consumption - computed in a situation where banks can engage in cross-border banking. The second part of this table reports …gures for a benchmark situation that does not account for cross-border bank ‡ows. All results are evaluated in terms of permanent consumption gains, with respect to a benchmark situation where the central bank implements an optimal monetary policy rule8 . First, neglecting macroprudential decisions, the value of parameters obtained for the optimal monetary rule gives high value to the parameter related to in‡ation in the interest rate rule while it ignores output stabilization. This is coherent with the …ndings of Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2007); Pariès et al. (2011); Quint and Rabanal (2013). The estimated interest rate rule leads to a welfare loss that represents -0.056% of permanent consumption in the monetary union. Optimal Parameters Taylor y Macroprudential 'h 'f h f Optimal Rule Empirical rule 2.88 1.96 0.00 - - 0.16 - - With Banking Flows a) total national b) partial symmetric c) total symmetric 2.88* 2.88* 2.88* 0* 0* 0* 2.59 30 30 18.60 0 0 Without Banking Flows d ) total national e) partial symmetric f ) total symmetric 2.88* 2.88* 2.88* 0* 0* 0* 2.43 30 30 30 0 0 - - Unconditional Consumption Gains (%) Union Core Periph. -0.056 -0.072 -0.036 0.05 0.05 0.02 0.886 0.821 0.690 -0.185 -0.176 -0.214 2.281 2.12 1.871 0.03 0.03 0.03 0.646 0.588 0.583 -0.045 -0.093 -0.087 1.550 1.479 1.460 Note: (*) denotes calibrated parameters on the optimal rule. Table 2: Welfare ranking of macroprudential policy Turning to the implementation of macroprudential policy measures, we compute the value of parameters i and 'i by maximizing the joint welfare of the two 8 In the quantitative simulation, we …rst search for weights attached to in‡ation and GDP y growth in the Taylor rule that gives the highest unconditional welfare of households. Here, we maintain the autoregressive parameter of the policy rule R at its estimated value since it has low e¤ects on welfare. Based on the grid search by 0:01 unit, we limit our attention to y policy coe¢ cients in the interval (1; 3] for , [0; 3] for as Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2007), and in the interval [0; 30] for macroprudential instruments i and 'i . Our grid search interval for macroprudential instruments is consistent with the …ndings of Gerali et al. (2010). The size of this interval is arbitrary, but but policy coe¢ cients larger than 30 would be di¢ cult to communicate to policymakers or the public Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (2007). 11 parts of the monetary union. First in situation (a), imposing no homogenous decision on these parameters, we …nd that there is a clear di¤erence between the two parts of the Eurozone, as the optimal value for the parameters is much lower for the core country group with h = 2:59 while f hits the higher bound. The capital constraint faced by peripheral banks tends to be e¤ective at diminishing the explosive growth of credit. Capital requirements helps in dampening the …nancial distress emanating from …nancial shocks as they are a major source of macroeconomic ‡uctuation in Periphery. Conversely, banks populating the core area do need important capital constraint to mitigate the systemic risk. With an homogenous treatment of countries regarding bank capital requirements in case (b), the parameter imposed to core counties is the same as the optimal national weight imposed to peripheral countries, which is clearly penalizing. Finally, imposing homogenous macroprudential decisions on the two instruments a¤ects the weight for both counties: it clearly increases the value of the parameter for core counties (that should get higher interest rate than needed, following the …nancial developments in this part of the monetary union) while correcting measures are lighter for the peripheral measures (the weight associated to both instruments is almost half of the value that was required on national grounds), thus leading to movements in the interest rates served to borrowers that are insu¢ cient to dampen all the …nancial disequilibrium in this part of the monetary union. In the last situation (c), unconditional consumption gains are the lowest: a common rule imposed by the …nancial regulator is even more penalizing than in the situation (b). As observed, the best outcome for the monetary union is the situation that account for national speci…cities in the setting of both lender and borrower parameters. This situation combines the coordination of decisions required to dampen the externality coming the implementation of a national macroprudential decision with the fact that the decision takes into account national …nancial developments in each part of the monetary union. However, as reported, the national consequences of macroprudential measures is heterogenous: peripheral countries are better o¤ (up to a gain of 2.281% of permanent consumption in the case of a national setting of parameters) while welfare diminishes in core countries (between -0.176% and -0.214% of permanent consumption loss). To evaluate the consequences of cross-border loans on these result, the last part of Table 2 reports the increase in permanent consumption that would be obtained in a situation of complete segmentation of the loan market. As noticed, the welfare gains are reduced. This feature may be explained by the combination of two factors: First, there is one supplementary …nancial friction in the monetary union; Second, as underlined in the previous section, both macroprudential instruments would account for the same loan value, which would make them closer substitutes. It should be noted, that even if the relative ranking of the implementation schemes is not a¤ected with respect to the situation with cross-border loans (imposing more symmetry in macroprudential measures is suboptimal), the two sit- 12 uation with symmetric features lead to very close results. Concentrating on the situation of core countries (that are looser for all macroprudential policy experiments), we clearly observe that the optimal situation for core country in the situation of cross-border loan is a situation where the parameter on bank capital requirement is set symmetrically for all countries. This feature disappears once neglecting cross-border banking. 3.2 Are Countries Encouraged to Coordinate Naturally? A Nash bargaining game As the optimal situation incurs losers and winners, a natural question arises whether it can be reached following national incentives. To evaluate the enforceability of the optimal cooperative solution we use a Nash bargaining game. Since our aim is to focus on how the macroprudential mandate should be shared among EMU members, we propose to borrow a convenient concept from game theory proposed by Nash Jr (1950, 1953). Following the bargaining theory, we examine how the surplus generated by macroprudential policy will be split between EMU participants when national governments may have incentive to set unilaterally macroprudential instruments. There are two participants in the game i = h; f (h for core and f for periphery). Each player considers two possible strategies: coordination and no coordination. If both players choose to coordinate macroprudential instruments, they maximize the welfare index of the monetary union Wu . If one country i chooses to deviate singly, it maximizes the welfare index of its country Wi to the detriment of the monetary union. Payo¤s are in terms of households unconditional consumption9 . As reported in Table 3 and Table 4, we …nd that each country would choose to follow the non cooperative strategy because incentives to deviate from the cooperative equilibrium are too large. In summary, federal institutions should enforce the cooperative solution, as national decisions would lead to a second best equilibrium. To reach the Pareto optimal equilibrium, it would thus be necessary to enforce cooperation through institutional incentives, as this situation cannot be reached on national incentives. We observe a welfare reversal when there is no cross-border lending in the monetary union, as nations will choose to cooperate naturally given the optimal national outcomes of the coordination situation. The cooperative equilibrium is the optimal one both on aggregate and on national features. As a conclusion, the possibility of bank to engage in cross-border loans creates a situation that requires a strong federal action to impose coordinated decisions on macroprudential measures. 4 Conclusion This paper has discussed the optimality of imposing homogenous macroprudential measures to all countries belonging to the Eurozone. Assessing the fact that 9 Unconditional consumption is evaluated as steady state in…nite streams of household consumption. 13 CORE PERIPHERY Coordination No Coordination f = 30; 'f = 0:05 f = 30; 'f = 0:04 Coordination h = 2:59; 'h = 0 ( -0.185, 2.281 ) 0.886 ( -0.204, 2.289 ) 0.879 No Coordination h = 7:95; 'h = 0 ( -0.153, 2.194 ) 0.866 ( -0.17, 2.205 ) 0.861 Note: Nash equilibrium is bold Table 3: Nash Equilibrium Payo¤s Matrix (in terms of unconditional consumption gains from leaving the simple optimal policy) CORE PERIPHERY Coordination No Coordination f = 30; 'f = 0:03 f = 30; 'f = 0:0303 Note: Coordination h = 2:43; 'h = 0 ( -0.045, 1.55 ) 0.646 ( -0.045 ,1.55 ) 0.646 No Coordination h = 0; 'h = 0 ( -0.133, 1.613 ) 0.624 ( -0.042, 0.514 ) 0.198 L h = L f = 0 (no cross-border lending). Table 4: Nash Equilibrium Payo¤s Matrix (in terms of unconditional consumption gains from leaving the simple optimal policy) without cross-border lending 14 the implementation of the macroprudential mandate has been set on cooperative decisions, we have developed a two-country DSGE model that accounts for some major features of the Eurozone (key role of the banking system, cross-border bank loans, heterogeneity in …nancial factors) to provide a quantitative evaluation of welfare gains coming from a more symmetric treatment of countries in the implementation of macroprudential measures. We separate the Eurozone in two parts (the core and the periphery) and evaluate how a macroprudential policy combining two instruments (namely, bank capital requirements and the evolution of the loan-to-income ratio) should be implemented. We more particularly contrasted three possibilities, ranking from a coordinated de…nition of macroprudential measures based on the choice of optimal national policy parameters to a homogeneous de…nition of all macroprudential measures. We …nd that optimal measures should be set cooperatively and should account for a heterogeneous treatment of countries as this policy leads to the highest increase of welfare on average in the monetary union. However, it creates losers (the core countries) and winners (the peripheral countries). Second, focusing on national developments, we …nd that the optimal solution that minimizes the permanent consumption loss for the core country needs to account for a symmetrical de…nition of the macroprudential parameter related to the bank capital requirement. Third, we …nd that the enforceability of the optimal cooperative solution needs an institutional decision, as leaving the choice of the equilibrium to national incentives leads to the choice of a non-cooperative outcome that is optimal on national counties but suboptimal in terms of joint welfare in the monetary union. These elements should be useful to analyze the proposed evolution of macroprudential policy organization in the Eurozone. There are important welfare gains in implementing national adjusted macroprudential measures, but a federal institution is necessary to oblige EU members to cooperate. Without a federal constraint on macroprudential policy implementation, the Euro members may choose not to coordinate which may signi…cantly reduce the welfare of the Eurosystem. 15 References Angelini, P., Neri, S., Panetta, F., 2012. Monetary and macroprudential policies. Angeloni, I., Faia, E., 2013. Capital regulation and monetary policy with fragile banks. Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (3), 311–324. Bailliu, J. N., Meh, C. A., Zhang, Y., 2012. Macroprudential rules and monetary policy when …nancial frictions matter. Bank of Canada. Beau, D., Clerc, L., Mojon, B., 2012. Macro-prudential policy and the conduct of monetary policy. Banque de France. Benes, J., Kumhof, M., 2011. Risky bank lending and optimal capital adequacy regulation. International Monetary Fund. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1999. The …nancial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. Handbook of macroeconomics 1, 1341–1393. Blanchard, O. J., Dell’Ariccia, M. G., Mauro, M. P., 2013. Rethinking macro policy II: getting granular. International Monetary Fund. Brooks, S. P., Gelman, A., 1998. General methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulations. Journal of computational and graphical statistics 7 (4), 434–455. Brunnermeier, M., De Gregorio, J., Eichengreen, B., El-Erian, M., Fraga, A., Ito, T., 2012. Banks and cross-border capital ‡ows: Policy challenges and regulatory responses. Brookings Committee on International Economic Policy and Reform. Brzoza-Brzezina, M., Kolasa, M., Makarski, K., 2013. Macroprudential policy instruments and economic imbalances in the euro area. Tech. rep. Christiano, L., Motto, R., Rostagno, M., 2010. Financial factors in economic ‡uctuations. Collard, F., Dellas, H., Diba, B., Loisel, O., 2012. Optimal Monetary and Prudential Policies. Banque de France. De Grauwe, P., 2010. The scienti…c foundation of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (dsge) models. Public choice 144 (3-4), 413–443. De Larosière, J., 2009. The High-Level Group on …nancial supervision in the EU: report. European Commission. Eyquem, A., Poutineau, J.-C., 2010. Markets integration and macroeconomic dispersion in a monetary union. Louvain Economic Review 76 (1), 5–30. Gelain, P., Lansing, K. J., Mendicino, C., 2012. House prices, credit growth, and excess volatility: Implications for monetary and macroprudential policy. International Journal of Central Banking. Gerali, A., Neri, S., Sessa, L., Signoretti, F. M., 2010. Credit and banking in a dsge model of the euro area. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (s1), 107–141. Gilchrist, S., Ortiz, A., Zakrajsek, E., 2009a. Credit risk and the macroeconomy: Evidence from an estimated dsge model. Unpublished manuscript, Boston University. Gilchrist, S., Sim, J., Zakrajsek, E., 2009b. Uncertainty, credit spreads, and investment dynamics. Tech. rep., Boston University mimeo. 16 Hirakata, N., Sudo, N., Ueda, K., 2009. Chained credit contracts and …nancial accelerators. Tech. rep., Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan. IMF, 2013. Implementing macroprudential policy - selected legal issues. Tech. rep., International Monetary Fund. Jondeau, E., Sahuc, J.-G., de France, B., 2006. Optimal monetary policy in an estimated DSGE model of the euro area with cross-country heterogeneity. Banque de France. Kannan, P., Rabanal, P., Scott, A., 2009. Monetary and macroprudential policy rules in a model with house price booms. International Monetary Fund, Research Department. Kincaid, G. R., Watson, M., 2013. The role of macroprudential policies and implications for international policy coordination. In: a Chatham House workshop and available at http://www. sant. ox. ac. uk/pefm/publications. html. Kolasa, M., 2009. Structural heterogeneity or asymmetric shocks? poland and the euro area through the lens of a two-country dsge model. Economic Modelling 26 (6), 1245–1269. Lambertini, L., Mendicino, C., Teresa Punzi, M., 2013. Leaning against boom–bust cycles in credit and housing prices. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (8), 1500–1522. Lubik, T., Schorfheide, F., 2006. A bayesian look at the new open economy macroeconomics. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2005, Volume 20. MIT Press, pp. 313–382. Medina, J. P., Roldós, J., 2013. Monetary and macroprudential policies to manage capital ‡ows. forthcoming IMF/WP. Nash, J., 1953. Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 128–140. Nash Jr, J. F., 1950. The bargaining problem. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 155–162. Nier, E., Osi´nski, J., Jácome, L. I., Madrid, P., 2011. Towards e¤ective macroprudential policy frameworks: An assessment of stylized institutional models. Tech. rep., International Monetary Fund. Pariès, M. D., Sørensen, C. K., Rodriguez-Palenzuela, D., 2011. Macroeconomic propagation under di¤erent regulatory regimes: Evidence from an estimated dsge model for the euro area. International Journal of Central Banking 7 (4), 49–113. Quint, D., Rabanal, P., 2013. Monetary and macroprudential policy in an estimated dsge model of the euro area. No. 13/209. IMF Working Paper. Rubio, M., Carrasco-Gallego, J. A., 2012. Macroprudential measures, housing markets, and monetary policy. Tech. rep., CEPREMAP. Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M., 2003. Closing small open economy models. Journal of international Economics 61 (1), 163–185. Schmitt-Grohé, S., Uribe, M., 2007. Optimal simple and implementable monetary and …scal rules. Journal of monetary Economics 54 (6), 1702–1725. Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2003. An estimated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model of the euro area. Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (5), 1123–1175. Smets, F., Wouters, R., 2007. Shocks and frictions in us business cycles: A bayesian dsge approach. American Economic Review 97 (3). 17 Suh, H., 2014. Dichotomy between macroprudential policy and monetary policy on credit and in‡ation. Economics Letters 122 (2), 144–149. Ueda, K., 2012. Banking globalization and international business cycles: Cross-border chained credit contracts and …nancial accelerators. Journal of International Economics 86 (1), 1–16. 18
© Copyright 2024 ExpyDoc