The Journal of Risk Model Validation (47–64) Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations Andrew Chernih University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW 2052, Australia; email: [email protected] Luc Henrard Catholic University of Louvain, School of Management, Place des Doyens 1, B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium; email: [email protected] Steven Vanduffel Vrije Universiteit Brussel, Pleinlaan 2, 1050 Brussels, Belgium; email: [email protected] The credit crisis has resulted in a new impetus for regulators in analyzing the framework for determining regulatory capital requirements; in particular, the assessment of credit risk will be challenged. Confronted with a lack of default statistics, it is common for industry practitioners to apply a financial approach known as Merton’s model of the firm, which also underpins modern solvency standards such as Basel II and Solvency II. However, while Merton’s theory is an academic beauty, its implementation does not make full use of available default statistics but, instead, relies on the concept of so-called asset correlations. We study the different estimates used for asset correlations that have appeared in the literature and analyze to what extent these estimates are in line with each other, with available default statistics and with our own findings. Our results are the same as most of those found in the literature but deviate from the results reported by some major software providers as well as from the Basel II and Solvency II figures. We offer several explanations to reconcile these differences and point to several other features that should not be overlooked when building credit portfolio models. 1 INTRODUCTION AND CONTEXT Over the past decade, banks and insurance companies have made considerable investments in the design and implementation of risk management systems. However, the financial crisis has increased the pressure on financial institutions and regulators to challenge and potentially revise all concepts and models used; credit risk models are particularly subject to such a critical review process. As far as credit risk is The authors would like to thank Alan Pitts and Karl Rappl (UBS), Jon Frye (Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago), Ivan Goethals (ING) and Bruno de Cleen (Rabobank) for helpful discussions and comments on an earlier draft. 47 48 A. Chernih et al concerned, it is clear that different obligors usually operate in related socio-economic environments so that, at least to some extent, their assets are impacted similarly; this points to a positive dependence between the default events. Therefore, we cannot readily resort to the law of large numbers to claim that for sufficiently large portfolios, the actual defaults will always be “as expected” and hence no capital will be needed. On the contrary, capital is necessary to absorb adverse deviations from what is expected during the time horizon at hand. To further elaborate on the need for capital, let us consider, for a given time horizon, an infinitely large homogeneous portfolio, ie, a portfolio with an infinite number of obligors having identical characteristics. In this case, all of the single default probabilities, denoted by qsingle , and pairwise default probabilities, denoted by qpair , will be similar across the different obligors involved. Furthermore, the socalled exposures-at-default (ie, the maximum losses in the case of a default) and loss-given-defaults (ie, the percentage of effective loss upon default) will be equal to each other. The quantities “exposures-at-default” and “loss-given-defaults” will be denoted by EAD and LGD, respectively. By additionally assuming that EAD and LGD are fixed numbers rather than random variables, it is easily shown that the standard deviation of the portfolio loss S, considered as a fraction of the total amount at risk (also known as the “portfolio unexpected loss”), can be expressed as: Stdev(S) = ρ D · Var(L) (1) Here, L is the individual obligor loss random variable (also expressed as a fraction), whose variance is given by: Var(L) = LGD2 · qsingle · (1 − qsingle ) (2) In Equation (1), ρ D ≥ 0 is the default correlation (for the given time horizon) between the different obligors: ρD = 2 qpair − qsingle qsingle · (1 − qsingle ) (3) Looking at (1), (2) and (3) together, we observe that Stdev(S) depends on the loss given defaults (LGD), the individual default probabilities (qsingle ) and the pairwise default probabilities (qpair ). While the process for estimating qsingle and LGD may be fairly under control, the intrinsic lack of sufficient default statistics puts a burden on the estimation of qpair and consequently casts doubt on the accuracy of the estimate for Stdev(S) and, ultimately, the required capital. Confronted with the apparent lack of default data, regulators and financial institutions resort to other techniques to derive the pairwise default probabilities qpair . In particular (see, for instance, Deloitte and Touche (2004)), they often rely on “Merton’s model of the firm”, which uses the intuitive idea of a default modeled as an adverse event triggered by an asset value moving in the wrong direction. Technically The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations speaking, Merton’s model amounts to assuming that, for the time horizon under consideration, the asset (log) returns are multivariate normally distributed, implying that a default for the ith borrower (where i = 1, 2, . . . , n) occurs when the change in asset value Ni drops below a certain threshold. Hence, in the context of our full homogeneous portfolio, the multivariate normal character of the asset returns implies that Ni can be expressed as: (4) N i = ρ A M + 1 − ρ A i so that: qsingle = Pr(Ni < c) = Pr( ρ A M + 1 − ρ A i < c) (5) Here, M and the i (i = 1, 2, . . . , n) are independent standard normally distributed random variables representing the common systemic factor (also called the state of the economy) and the idiosyncratic risks, respectively. Furthermore, ρ A ≥ 0 is the (asset) correlation coefficient, c is the constant threshold value and (·) is the distribution function of a standard normally distributed random variable, with inverse −1 (·). Of course, joint defaults will be driven by the correlated asset returns, and it is easily shown that: qpair = ρ A (−1 (qsingle ), −1 (qsingle )) (6) where ρ A (· , ·) is used to denote the distribution function of a bivariate standard normal random pair with correlation coefficient ρ A ; see Crouhy et al (2000) for more details. Note that in Equation (5), the probability qsingle (= (c)) does not depend on the precise state of the economy M and is therefore unconditional. On the other hand, Equation (5) can also be used to define conditional probabilities, which we denote by qsingle (m), as follows: c − ρAm qsingle (m) = Pr i < 1 − ρA −1 (qsingle ) − ρ A m (7) = 1 − ρA The conditional probability qsingle (m) is the probability that there will be a default given that the (future) state of the economy M is known to be equal to m. It is important to observe that under Merton’s firm value model, Equation (6) provides an explicit relation between the (unconditional) parameters qsingle , qpair and ρ A , which enables the “translation” of default correlations into “equivalent” asset correlations and vice versa. Indeed, if default statistics have been used to derive estimates for qsingle and qpair (and thus also the default correlation ρ D ), then Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 49 50 A. Chernih et al Equation (6) can be used to extract the implied asset correlation ρ A . On the other hand, if qsingle and ρ A are available, then we can use Equation (6) to derive qpair and hence, by Equation (3), also the implied default correlation ρ D . In this respect, we remark that in the literature on credit correlations it is now common to use asset correlations (rather than default correlations) to discuss and compare the different findings. Merton’s firm value model can also be used to derive the loss distribution of the infinitely large homogeneous portfolio exactly; consequently, the maximal loss at a given confidence level p, namely the “portfolio value-at-risk”, denoted by VaRp (S), can be determined as well. Indeed, by using the fact that conditional on the state of the economy M the default events are independent, it follows from the law of large numbers that, essentially: VaRp (S) = VaRp (E(S | M)) = VaRp (LGD · qsingle (M)) (8) Thus we find that: −1 (qsingle ) + ρ A · −1 (p) VaRp (S) = LGD · 1 − ρA (9) Formula (9) can be traced back to Vasicek (2002) and is widely used. In fact, many credit risk portfolio models rely on (variants of) Merton’s model of the firm as summarized above. For example, Basel II relies on (9) to determine the required capital that banks need for their credit portfolios; see Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006, pp. 64–66) and Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2005). Also, the upcoming Solvency II framework is likely to use formula (9), with a minimum level of 50% for the asset correlations, for determining capital charges to cover for exposure to reinsurance or derivative counterparts. We refer to the Committee of Insurance and Occupational Pension Supervisors (2008) for an overview of the technical Solvency II guidelines, and to Doff (2008) for a detailed critical analysis of the whole Solvency II framework. We would also like to point out that under the stated assumptions of an infinitely large homogeneous portfolio, Equation (8) holds generally, so that in such instances capital formulae will always be determined essentially by the properties of the random variable qsingle (M). In fact, under Merton’s paradigm, qsingle (·) is determined by (7) whereas M is a standard normal random variable representing the uncertain future state of the economy, and this gives rise to formula (9) for VaRp (S). However, if other assumptions are made with regards to qsingle (·) and M, then obviously other capital formulae will result. For example, let us assume that defaults indeed occur according to Merton’s paradigm but that, in addition, we are able to predict with certainty the state of the economy, ie, it is known ex ante that M will be equal to The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations some m∗ . Then formula (8) will still hold, but now we find that: VaRp (S) = VaRp (LGD · qsingle (m∗ )) = LGD · qsingle (m∗ ) (10) so that VaRp (S) is nothing more than a (conditional) expected loss in this case. The example makes clear that value-at-risk and capital calculations are intimately connected with the design of the rating system used to generate default probabilities. If a so-called through-the-cycle rating system is put in place that generates (unconditional) probabilities qsingle as in (5), where M is unknown, then formula (9) is appropriate for determining value-at-risk. In contrast, if we have in place a perfect point-in-time rating system where M is known with certainty, then formula (10) is correct. In fact, if capital were taken to be the difference between the value-at-risk and expected loss, then no capital would even be needed because “everything will evolve as expected”; see also Cornaglia and Morone (2009) for some recent work on this topic. In this paper, we use Merton’s paradigm as the basis and the results of the analysis have to be understood in this context. While it is fair to say that Merton’s idea has enhanced the understanding and modeling of credit portfolio risk in significant ways, it needs to be stressed that, in practice, its implementation relies on asset value data, which is not directly observable but can only be derived (through a series of other models and assumptions) from equity value data. Indeed, although under the Merton paradigm default statistics are likely to be used to derive estimates for the single default probabilities qsingle , the estimation of the pairwise probabilities qpair (see (6)), and thus also the portfolio unexpected loss Stdev(S) as well as the portfolio value-at-risk VaRp (S) (see (8)), is not backed fully by default statistics but, rather, relies on asset value data; see also Crouhy et al (2000). It is important to keep in mind that, even though the wider availability of asset value data along with Merton’s appealing theory may provide some feelings of comfort, ultimately the performance of any credit default risk model needs to be assessed using default statistics. In this respect we agree with Frye (2008), who stated that “many naïve risk managers rely on asset correlations without checking the results”. It would therefore be of interest to review the different estimates used for asset correlations that have been mentioned in the literature, analyze to what extent these estimates agree with each other, and try to offer explanations for any observed differences. At the same time, some of these explanations may shed light on other features that should not be overlooked when building credit portfolio models (which involves considering more than just correlations), and we provide some insight with regard to the impact that these may have on the results. As far as we know, this is the first study that provides a global overview of findings in the literature on the level of asset correlations, and we will compare the results of our study, which is based on a large sample of monthly asset value data, with a series of other studies. These other studies can be divided roughly into Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 51 52 A. Chernih et al two categories. One kind of study uses observed default data to calculate single and pairwise default frequencies, from which default correlations can then be derived directly; this category of research includes Gordy (2000), Frey and McNeil (2003), Dietsch and Petey (2004), Jobst and de Servigny (2005) and de Servigny and Renault (2002). The second category of work involves the use of asset or equity values to obtain estimates for the asset correlations; papers in this category include Duellmann et al (2008), Lopez (2002), Pitts (2004), Zeng and Zhang (2001) and Akhavein et al (2005). The last two papers report findings from Moody’s KMV (MKMV) and Fitch Ratings, respectively. We find that the results of our study are broadly in line with the most of those in the literature, and several plausible reasons have already been documented to explain observed differences. On the other hand, all these results deviate from what has been reported by MKMV and Fitch Ratings, as well as from the Solvency II and Basel II figures. We offer some potential explanations in an attempt to reconcile these differences. Firstly, we provide evidence that credit risk modeling is subject to significant modeling risk, which implies that some stakeholders will, for reasons of conservatism, simply prefer to use higher correlations than what has actually been observed. In particular, this could explain the high level of correlations used in Basel II and Solvency II. Secondly, we analyze two sources of dependence that might exist in a credit portfolio and that are typically overlooked by modelers, namely, dependent loss-given-defaults and the presence of group effects. This may also explain, to some extent, why some software providers, rating agencies and regulators use higher-than-observed correlations. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 gives an overview of results in the existing literature, whereas Section 3 describes the results we have obtained. Section 4 discusses all of the various results and offers some potential explanations to reconcile the observed differences. Finally, Section 5 contains some concluding remarks. 2 ASSET CORRELATIONS FROM THE LITERATURE 2.1 Asset correlations using default data In Table 1 (see page 53) we report the asset correlations from a variety of studies that made use of observed default data. When the equivalent asset correlations were not explicitly mentioned in the study, we used Equation (6) to extract these from the reported default correlations. Note that all (inherent) default correlations are unconditional and that the abovementioned studies have used a variety of methods to estimate these. For example, both Gordy (2000) and Cespedes (2002) appear to have first estimated the standard deviation of the portfolio loss corresponding to the population at hand, and then relied on Equation (1) to derive the default correlation. Other studies, such as Hamerle et al (2003a), use a straightforward model-free technique; for more details, see Lucas (1995). The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations TABLE 1 Asset correlations derived from default data. Source study Default data source Results (%) Gordy (2000, Table 2) Cespedes (2002) Hamerle et al (2003a) Hamerle et al (2003b, Table 1) Frey and McNeil (2003, Table 1) Dietsch and Petey (2004) Jobst and de Servigny (2005) Duellmann and Scheule (2003) Jakubik (2006) S&P Moody’s Unknown S&P 1982–1999 S&P 1981–2000 Coface 1994–2001 S&P 1981–2003 DB 1987–2000 BF 1988–2003 1.5–12.5 10 Max 2.3 0.4–6.04 6.5–6.9–9.1 0.12–10.72 4.7–14.6 0.5–6.4 5.7 S&P: Standard and Poor’s; DB: Deutsche Bundesbank; BF: Bank of Finland. TABLE 2 Asset correlations derived from asset value data. Source study Duellmann et al (2008) Zeng and Zhang (2001) Akhavein et al (2005) Lopez (2002) de Servigny and Renault (2002) Asset data source Results (%) MKMV Credit Monitor MKMV source Equity MKMV Portfolio Manager Equity 10.2 9.46–19.98 20.92–24.09 11.25 6 We mention that, in addition to the studies listed in Table 1, Hamerle et al (2003a) used the same data as in Boegelein et al (2002), comprising default data from Canada, France, Germany, the UK, Italy, Japan, South Korea, Singapore, Sweden and the US. There is also a study by Vassiliev (2006), which uses default data from UBS to calculate asset correlations that “are in the range reported in external studies (eg, Dietsch and Petey (2004))”. From Table 1 we can conclude that the different results, while using different estimation techniques to cope with default statistics from the US, Canada, Switzerland, France, Germany, Finland, the UK, Italy, Japan, South Korea and Singapore that cover different data periods as well, yield broadly consistent correlation estimates in the range of 1%–12%, approximately. Note that the default data used in these studies was typically available at a one-year horizon, meaning that the implied asset correlations correspond to a one-year time horizon in these instances as well. 2.2 Asset correlations using asset value data Using asset value data as input, we can estimate asset correlations directly in a straightforward way (and also move on to default correlations if necessary). Several studies exist that have made use of asset value data from various sources; the results are summarized in Table 2. Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 53 54 A. Chernih et al Note that, in contrast to studies based on default data, most asset value studies use a weekly or monthly horizon to calculate asset returns and derive asset correlations. Duellmann et al (2008), however, calculated two-year asset correlations using rolling 24-month time windows. Since their study used only eight years of asset return data (which means four distinct 24-month periods), this may be insufficient for correlation estimates. Akhavein et al (2005) used equity values and a proprietary software to report five-year correlations. Zeng and Zhang (2001) do not release full details concerning how they built their asset correlation model or the data they used, and their model is designed to be used in conjunction with the MKMV Portfolio Manager software. Lopez (2002) also did not disclose details of the asset data used, only that MKMV Portfolio Manager was used for the analysis. Presumably, MKMV Portfolio Manager is based on the same raw data (from MKMV Credit Monitor) that we used in our analysis, but there is no formal guarantee of this. We also point out that de Servigny and Renault (2002) effectively utilized equity correlations to obtain an average correlation of 6%. As well as the studies listed in Table 2, we mention that Basel II also uses asset correlations ranging from 8% to 24%, with the exact value depending on individual firm characteristics such as rating and asset size, to determine the required capital that banks need for their corporate credit portfolios; see the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006, pp. 64–66). Finally, the upcoming Solvency II framework is likely to set a minimum level of 50% for the asset correlations in determining capital charges to cover for exposure to reinsurance or derivative counterparts; see the Committee of Insurance and Occupational Pension Supervisors (2008). The results in Table 2 suggest that, compared to using default data, the use of asset value data to estimate asset correlations appears to give rise to slightly higher estimates in general; see Frye (2005) for comments in a similar vein. Gordy and Heitfield (2002) have shown that using the specifications of Merton’s model in the statistical procedure for estimating asset correlations based on default data is likely to yield higher results in general; see also Miu and Ozdemir (2007) for related work in the context of estimating default probabilities. It seems that using model-free methods to estimate asset correlations based on default data may be subject to some downward bias, hence explaining why the asset correlations from Table 1 tend to be lower. Nevertheless, such downward bias is only really correct and meaningful if the real default data process is (broadly) in line with Merton’s theory, which is, owing to the scarcity of observed default data, difficult to prove in a statistically meaningful way. In other words, if real defaults do not occur according to the Merton mechanism, then there is no real guarantee that the estimates in Table 1 are too low; we should also keep in mind that model-free procedures are by nature more robust with respect to model specification. Finally, we remark that the studies in Zeng and Zhang (2001) and Akhavein et al (2005) give significantly larger results than any other study reported so far. The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations 3 OUR ASSET CORRELATIONS 3.1 The data used The source of the asset value data used in this study is MKMV Credit Monitor. Several other papers, such as Pitts (2004) and Duellmann et al (2008), have used the same raw data source. In both of these papers it is stated that this asset data should be corrected for the impact of corporate actions and potential data errors. Accordingly, the data was cleaned to remove outliers, asset values were adjusted for debt issues and buybacks, and those months for which asset value data was not available were removed from consideration. The monthly returns were then calculated as the ratio of the ending (market) asset value minus the value of liabilities issued during that month to the starting (market) asset value. This means that for each of the 20,144 companies, we had up to 107 months of return data available over the time period from March 1998 to March 2007. To the best of our knowledge, this is the largest sample that has ever been used for an asset correlation study. Whenever a pair of companies had at least 40 months’ worth of data in common, a correlation was calculated. The companies were aggregated into 336 clusters based on asset size, activity sector, probability of default and world region. There is some evidence from previous studies that these are factors that may differentiate asset correlation; see Lopez (2002), Duellmann and Scheule (2003) and Dietsch and Petey (2004), among others. 3.2 Our main findings For our 336 asset clusters, the average intra-cluster asset correlation was 11.1% (this was obtained by calculating for each cluster the average of all pairwise correlations that exist within the cluster and then averaging over all clusters); the average intercluster asset correlation was 6.3% (obtained by calculating for each pair of clusters the average of all pairwise correlations that exist between two assets from the two different clusters, and then taking the average over all combinations of two different clusters). A graph of the inter-cluster correlation, grouped by asset size band and client rating, is shown in Figure 1 (on page 56). As expected, the correlations increase with asset size (because the greater the asset size the more systemic the obligor’s risk profile typically becomes). Moreover, in line with common expectations, we see that correlations decrease with increasing probability of default (because, in general, there is an inverse relation between default probability and asset size). 4 DISCUSSION The results we have obtained from using the monthly asset return data are consistent with most of the values found in the existing literature, and it is fair to say that results in the literature are in general very closely aligned (with the exception of Akhavein Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 55 A. Chernih et al FIGURE 1 Asset correlations by S&P rating and asset size band. AAA–BB+ BB–B- B+ B–C 8.00% 7.00% Average asset correlation 56 6.00% 5.00% 4.00% 3.00% 2.00% 1.00% 0.00% Very small Small Medium Asset size bands Large Within each asset size band, the four default probability groups are plotted from left to right in decreasing order of S&P rating (ie, increasing order of default probability). et al (2005), who reports equity correlations as a substitute for asset correlations using return data spanning a five-year horizon, and Zeng and Zhang (2001)). Thus, on the one hand, there appears to be a consensus in the literature on the range of values for asset correlations; but, on the other hand, the question arises as to why Fitch Ratings and MKMV, as well as Basel II and Solvency II, use significantly different values. We now proceed to offer a number of possible explanations. Some of these explanations may shed light on other features that should not be overlooked when building credit portfolio models (correlations are not the only component to take into account), and we provide some insight into the impact that these factors may have on the results. 4.1 Correlations do not measure dependence fully First, let us remark that any given set of assumptions regarding the loss-givendefaults, exposures-at-default, single default probabilities and asset or default correlations will never be complete enough to estimate the portfolio loss distribution with certainty. Indeed, since correlations are related to individual and pairwise but not multiple default probabilities, they do not provide a full picture of the dependence that exists within a portfolio. In fact, all joint default probabilities need to be determined when estimating a credit loss distribution in general and the portfolio valueat-risk in particular. Unfortunately, however, even estimating a triple-wise default The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations probability based on default data is a cumbersome exercise; so, in a credit context, obtaining a full picture of dependence is a far-from-trivial task, and this problem has a negative impact on the potential accuracy of the estimated loss distribution. This is the reason why most companies make an implicit or explicit assumption regarding the dependence structure; the assumption of multivariate normally distributed asset returns in Merton’s model of the firm is just an (influential) example of such practice. In this respect, we point out that it is even perfectly possible to construct models that all preserve a given Stdev(S) while giving very different results for the portfolio value-at-risk VaRp (S). Let us now assume that the normalized asset returns Ni evolve as follows: Ni = M · IM<d + −1 ((d) + (i ) · (−d)) · (1 − IM<d ) (11) where IM<d is an indicator random variable and d is a threshold value reflecting “bad times”. Note that while the different Ni are still normally distributed, they are no longer multivariate normally distributed. Loosely speaking, the asset returns are fully dependent (ie, exhibit maximal “tail correlation”) when the market is in a deep recession, and they are unrelated otherwise. Then, whenever p > (−d) > 1 − qsingle holds, we will find that the portfolio value-at-risk at the confidence level p, namely VaRp (S), is exactly equal to the maximal loss that can possibly be incurred, ie, the loss when all obligors default. For example, let us consider a homogeneous portfolio with qsingle = 1.5%, LGD = 100% and ρ A = 7%. Then, using Monte Carlo simulation, we find that (−d) is approximately equal to 99%. Hence, when p > 99%, under the model specification (11) for the asset returns we have that VaRp (S) = 100%, whereas under the (Merton) specification (4) we obtain, by formula (9), that VaRp (S) = 6.12%. Thus, while the parameter values for LGD, EAD, qsingle and ρ A are exactly the same in both models, the results produced are substantially different; see also Chernih et al (2008) for more information in the same vein. Confronted with significant intrinsic model error, some stakeholders may, for reasons of conservatism, prefer to use higher correlations than what is actually observed. This could, in particular, explain the high level of correlations used in Basel II and Solvency II. 4.2 Effect of dependent loss-given-defaults Furthermore, even the calculation of the portfolio unexpected loss is significantly impacted by (explicit or implicit) modeling assumptions. Indeed, the computation of portfolio unexpected loss is dependent on whether the loss-given-defaults are deterministic or stochastic, the dependence between them, and possible dependence between default events and loss-given-defaults. We will focus on the issue of dependent loss-given-defaults. To this end, let us consider again an infinitely large homogeneous portfolio. However, while we still assume that the exposures-at-default are fixed, we will Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 57 58 A. Chernih et al consider three different methods to deal with the loss-given-defaults. The first model assumes stochastic dependent loss-given-defaults, the second model assumes stochastic independent loss-given-defaults, and the third model assumes deterministic loss-given-defaults. It is very likely that the first (and most sophisticated) model leads to the most accurate description of the portfolio risk. Indeed, different lossgiven-defaults are likely to be positively related to each other, because they are driven by asset value processes that are most likely positively correlated as well. All other things being equal, using the second or third model for loss-givendefaults will result in a lower estimate for the portfolio unexpected loss, Stdev(S), than would be obtained from the first model. Alternatively, to achieve the best estimate of the unexpected loss (defined as the result from the first model), the other approaches will need to use higher asset correlations than those used in the first model. This naturally leads to the question: how much higher? From Dhaene et al (2006) we have the following equation for the loss correlation ρ L between individual random credit losses: ρL = A+B Var(L) (12) where: 2 ]ρ LGD · Var(LGD) A = [ρ D · qsingle · (1 − qsingle ) + qsingle (13) B = ρ D · qsingle · (1 − qsingle ) · E 2 (LGD) (14) and: Here, ρ LGD denotes the correlation between the loss-given-defaults for two distinct credit risks, and E(LGD) is the expected value of the random loss-given-default while Var(LGD) is its variance. Furthermore, the variance of an individual loss, Var(L), is now given by: Var(L) = E 2 (LGD) · qsingle · (1 − qsingle ) + qsingle · Var(LGD) (15) For the infinitely large portfolio as described above, it can be shown that the portfolio unexpected loss expressed as a fraction of the total amount at risk equals: Stdev(S) = ρ L · Var(L) (16) We can calculate Stdev(S) using the first model and then calculate what the required asset correlation should be for the second and third models in order to attain the same Stdev(S). Note that (16) reduces to (1) when ρ LGD = 0, meaning that for an infinitely large portfolio it makes absolutely no difference whether loss-given-defaults are stochastic and independent or deterministic. Hence the required asset correlations for the second and third models will be the same. We calculated the “corrected” asset correlations for various values of qsingle , 2 σ (LGD) and ρ LGD . The expected value E(LGD) was fixed at 50%. Eight results are The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations TABLE 3 Corrected asset correlations, for given values of qsingle , ρ LGD , Var(LGD) and original asset correlation, that are needed to keep the same portfolio unexpected loss, assuming an infinitely large portfolio of obligors with ρ LGD = 0. qsingle (%) ρ LGD (%) Var(LGD) (%) Original asset correlation (%) Required asset correlation (%) 25 100 25 100 25 100 25 100 25 25 4.2 4.2 25 25 4.2 4.2 13.96 13.96 13.96 13.96 8.45 8.45 8.45 8.45 16.84 23.32 14.48 15.94 16.88 37.53 9.93 14.18 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 9.75 9.75 9.75 9.75 presented in Table 3. For example, the first row represents a portfolio of obligors with a qsingle of 0.21%, a ρ LGD of 25% and a σ 2 (LGD) of 25%. The original (estimated) asset correlation is 13.96%, but an asset correlation of 16.84% needs to be used to keep the same value of Stdev(S). From Table 3 we observe that the relative change from the true asset correlation to the corrected asset correlation (to account for dependent loss-given-defaults implicitly) can be tremendous. The effect of dependent loss-given-defaults may also explain the possible need to use higher asset correlations in portfolio models. Often, though it might seem that asset correlations are being measured, these are in fact used as input for calculating the overall credit loss distribution. Thus, while best estimates of asset correlations are typically in the region of 0%–10%, obtaining best estimates for credit loss distributions might require the use of higher asset correlations (to account for other sources of dependencies). For example, in the MKMV Portfolio Manager software, the loss-given-defaults appear to always be modeled as mutually independent random variables, which may explain a need for upward adjustment of the originally derived asset correlations to prevent potential underestimation of the portfolio unexpected loss. 4.3 Group effects Another kind of dependence that can exist in a portfolio and that is frequently overlooked by modelers arises from group effects. A credit risk portfolio often contains individual policies that have strong legal or economical ties. A conglomerate (mother company) may be composed of different legal entities (daughter companies), and a default of the former may lead to default of all of the latter. In fact, such dependence is often taken into consideration when assessing the default probabilities within a group of related companies; because the default of a daughter company Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 59 60 A. Chernih et al may be prevented by the mother company, in the presence of group effects, daughter companies might be assigned better ratings (and hence lower default probabilities) than they would have received as stand-alone entities. Unfortunately, while such group effects are often considered in the modeling of individual default probabilities, they are almost never taken into account when modeling the dependence, and this can lead to underestimation of the risk. Indeed, Vanduffel et al (2008) used comonotonic theory (see Vanduffel (2005)) to extend a celebrated actuarial collective risk model (see Panjer (1981)), known in the industry as CreditRisk+ , to account for such group effects. Their numerical examples showed that such group effects can have a significant impact on the loss distribution, especially in the tail. Group effects are likely to increase the need for capital, but most credit risk models fall short of capturing such effects. Therefore some stakeholders may opt to consider the effect implicitly, by artificially increasing the levels of the asset correlations. 4.4 Effect of the horizon The correlation estimates reported in the literature do not necessarily all correspond to the same risk horizon, and this may create bias when comparing the results. Indeed, a priori, it is not obvious that observed asset returns involve the same correlation across different horizons. While this would be true when asset returns are multivariate normally distributed, it is by no means a general truth. Also, default correlations may vary depending on the length of the horizon used. The effect of the horizon has been studied for equity correlations (see, for example, Koyluoglu et al (2003)) but less so for asset correlations. For the most part this is due to data limitations. Default data is generally only available to use at a one- or five-year level. In Jobst and de Servigny (2005), although default correlations were observed to increase with increasing horizon (using one-, three- and five-year time periods), the probability of defaults also increased, thus keeping the asset correlation broadly constant. However, in de Servigny and Renault (2002) some evidence for increasing asset correlations was found. Moving from a one-year time period to a longer time period gives inconclusive results. Using asset returns requires the use of shorter time periods, owing to less data being available. Given that the general advice is to use at least 50 values to estimate a correlation, using annual returns is impossible with the number of years of asset return data available. Some commonly used alternatives are to calculate either weekly or monthly asset returns and then use these as annual asset correlations. Some studies, such as Duellmann et al (2008), use rolling-window time periods to calculate correlations; that is, overlapping time periods are used. However, this approach does not increase the effective dimension of the calculations. Using rolling 24-month time periods with eight years of data may lead to more observations, but consecutive observations are now built on almost identical data, differing by only one The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations month at the beginning and one month at the end: there are still merely four distinct 24-month periods to work with. Our study was based on monthly asset returns, and the results suggest that using monthly asset correlations as a proxy for asset correlations gives values that are in line with default correlations observed from default data. Generally speaking, we believe that the statistics used to parameterize the model should be aligned with the risk horizon chosen. The impact of the horizon on asset correlations is certainly a topic that requires further research. 4.5 Effect of the rating system We recall from the introduction that rating systems and capital frameworks should be aligned in principle. Indeed, in the context of an infinitely large portfolio, Equation (8) holds more generally and reveals the close connection between the portfolio value-at-risk VaRp (S) and the stochastic default probability qsingle (M). Rating systems may differ in the way m → qsingle (m) is modeled, as well as with respect to the modeled stochasticity of M. For example, under a perfect point-intime rating system, the stochasticity of M vanishes, so that no deviations around the expected losses will be observed (for an infinitely large portfolio) and hence no capital is needed to account for possible shocks (as it will be accounted for in the provisions). In fact, formula (9) is only fully appropriate when Merton’s model of the firm has been used to generate the (unconditional) probabilities qsingle . Financial institutions often rely on internal rating systems to determine default probabilities and on (Merton’s) formula (9) to determine capital requirements. As the underpinning frameworks do not comply with each other per se, practitioners may for reasons of conservativeness opt for artificially increasing the levels of the asset correlations used in formula (9). This may also contribute to explaining why Basel II and Solvency II are using higher-than-observed asset correlations, though it still does not seem to provide a satisfactory explanation for the higher levels of asset correlations used by Moody’s KMV. 5 FINAL REMARKS Observed default data is a priori the best source to use for estimating single and pairwise default frequencies; default correlations can then also be derived. However, confronted with a lack of sufficient default data, banks, insurance companies and software providers often resort to equity or asset correlations. Such correlations are then transformed into default correlations by means of the so-called Merton model of the firm. While the additional sophistication and the availability of asset value data may provide some feelings of comfort, this comes at the cost of significant model risk. Indeed, asset data itself is not observable but needs to be derived from equity data using option models; see Crouhy et al (2000). A discussion on which kind of asset correlations should be used and in how much detail they need to be modeled is, in our view, a bit off-topic. Credit risk portfolio Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 61 62 A. Chernih et al models are by nature subject to tremendous model risk anyway, and correlations are only one piece of a very difficult puzzle, which unfortunately can never be fully completed. In this respect, we believe that complex models by no means guarantee more accurate results. For example, in view of the earlier considerations, it seems fair to say that the added value a sophisticated multi-factor model for asset correlations brings to the accuracy of capital calculations is questionable. In our opinion, credit portfolio models should be kept as simple and transparent as possible, capturing essential drivers such as correlation, dependent loss-givendefaults and group effects in a straightforward and consistent way, and making use of default (loss) statistics as much as possible (including the use of externally available default data). A candidate credit portfolio model that appears to meet several of these criteria is the (one-factor) CreditRisk+ model, introduced by Crédit Suisse and known in actuarial circles as an example of a collective risk model. Indeed, the natural parameterization of this model is based on default statistics, calculations can be done analytically, and features such as group dependence and dependent lossgiven-defaults can be readily accounted for; see, for instance, Vanduffel et al (2008) and Vandendorpe et al (2008) for further information. REFERENCES Akhavein, J. D., Kocagil, A. E., and Neugebauer, M. (2005). A comparative empirical study of asset correlations. Special Report, Quantitative Financial Research, Fitch Ratings. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2005). An explanatory note on the Basel II IRB risk weight functions. URL: http://www.bis.org/bcbs/irbriskweight.htm. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2006). Basel II: international convergence of capital measurement and capital standards: a revised framework – comprehensive version. URL: http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs128.htm. Boegelein, A., Hamerle, A., Rauhmeier, R., and Scheule, H. (2002). Modelling default rate dynamics in the CreditRisk+ framework. Risk 15(10), S24–S28. Cespedes, J. (2002). Credit risk modelling and Basel II. Algo Research Quarterly 5(1), 57. Chernih, A., Maj, M., and Vanduffel, S. (2008). The use and abuse of copulas in economic capital calculations. Belgian Actuarial Bulletin 7(1), 19–23. Committee of Insurance and Occupational Pension Supervisors (CEIOPS) (2008). Quantitative impact study 4. URL: http://www.ceiops.eu/content/view/716/334/. Cornaglia, A., and Morone, M. (2009). Rating philosophy and dynamic properties of internal rating systems: a general framework and an application to backtesting. Working Paper, Intesa Sanpaolo. Crouhy, M., Galei, D., and Mark, R. (2000). A comparative analysis of current credit risk models. Journal of Banking and Finance 24, 57–117. Deloitte and Touche (2004). Deloitte’s Global Risk Management Survey. Dhaene, J., Goovaerts, M. J., Koch, R., Olieslagers, R., Romijn, O., and Vanduffel, S. (2006). Consistent assumptions for modeling credit loss correlations. Journal of Actuarial Practice 13, 173–182. The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010 Reconciling credit correlations Dietsch, M., and Petey, J. (2004). Should SME exposures be treated as retail or corporate exposures? A comparative analysis of default probabilities and asset correlations in French and German SMEs. Journal of Banking and Finance 28, 773–788. Doff, R. (2008). A critical analysis of the Solvency II proposals. The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance: Issues and Practice 33(2), 193–206. Duellmann, K., and Scheule, H. (2003). Determinants of the asset correlations of German corporations and implications for regulatory capital. Working Paper, Deutsches Bundesbank. Duellmann, K., Scheicher, M., and Schmieder, C. (2008). Asset correlations and credit portfolio risk: an empirical analysis. The Journal of Credit Risk 4(2), 37–62. Frey, R., and McNeil, A. (2003). Dependent defaults in models of portfolio credit risk. The Journal of Risk 6(1), 59–92. Frye, J. (2005). Not a stock answer. Risk 18(8), 78. Frye, J. (2008). Correlation and asset correlation in the structural portfolio model. The Journal of Credit Risk 4(2), 73–94. Gordy, M. (2000). A Comparative anatomy of credit risk models. Journal of Banking and Finance 24(1–2), 119–149. Gordy, M., and Heitfield, E. (2002). Estimating default correlations from short panels of credit rating performance data. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Board. Hamerle, A., Liebig T., and Roesch, D. (2003a). Benchmarking asset correlations. Risk 16, 77–81. Hamerle, A., Liebig, T., and Roesch, D. (2003b). Credit risk factor modeling and the Basel II IRB approach. Discussion Paper, Deutsches Bundesbank. Jakubik, P. (2006). Does credit risk vary with economic cycles? The case of Finland. Working Paper, Institute of Economic Studies, Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University in Prague. Jobst, N. J., and de Servigny, A. (2005). An empirical analysis of equity default swaps II: multivariate insights. Working Paper, Standard & Poor’s. Koyluoglu, H. U., Wilson, T., and Yague, M. (2003). The eternal challenge of understanding imperfections. Working Paper, Mercer Oliver Wyman. Lopez, J. A. (2002). The empirical relationship between average asset correlation, firm probability of default and asset size. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Lucas, D. (1995). Default correlation and credit analysis. Journal of Fixed Income (March), 76–87. Miu, P., and Ozdemir, B. (2007). Estimating and validating long-run probability of default with respect to Basel II requirements, The Journal of Risk Model Validation 2(2), 1–39. Panjer, H. H. (1981). Recursive evaluation of a family of compound distributions. ASTIN Bulletin 12, 22–26. Pitts, A. (2004). Correlated defaults: let’s go back to the data. Risk 17(6), 75–79. de Servigny, A., and Renault, O. (2002). Default correlation: empirical evidence. Working Paper, Standard & Poor’s. Research Paper www.thejournalofriskmodelvalidation.com 63 64 A. Chernih et al Vandendorpe, A., Ho, N., Vanduffel, S., and Van Dooren, P. (2008). On the parameterization of the CreditRisk+ model for estimating credit portfolio risk. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 42, 736–745. Vanduffel, S. (2005). Comonotonicity: from risk measurement to risk management. PhD Thesis, University of Amsterdam. Vanduffel, S., Aver, B., Cernih, A., Henrard, L., and Ribas, C. (2008). Stress testing the impact of group dependence on credit portfolio risk. Stress Testing for Financial Institutions: Applications, Regulations and Techniques, Rösch, D. and Scheule, H. (eds). Risk Books, London, pp. 93–109. Vasicek, O. (2002). Loan portfolio value, Risk 15(12), 160–162. Vassiliev, A. (2006). Estimating dependence of credit risks. Presentation, Eurobanking 2006, Dubrovnik, Croatia, 21–24 May. Zeng, B., and Zhang, J. (2001). An empirical assessment of asset correlation models. Research Paper, Moody’s KMV. URL: http://www.moodyskmv.com/research/files/wp/emp_assesment.pdf. The Journal of Risk Model Validation Volume 4/Number 2, Summer 2010
© Copyright 2024 ExpyDoc